< < <
Date Index > > > |
The world press on AGF: AGF in the 10 years Reuters archive by Tausch, Arno 19 June 2001 10:36 UTC |
< < <
Thread Index > > > |
This is a fascinating glimpse of debates in world system theory, as reflected by the world press according to Reuters Business Briefing archive Arno Tausch (no other selection criterium was used - just 10 years of articles on AGF) 11Mai2001 AUSTRALIA: Weekend Review - Rome and the East - a classic balls-up. By Paul Monk Paul Monk is senior fellow of the Australian Thinking Skills Institute (www.austhink.org) and an honorary research fellow in Asian studies at La Trobe University. Paul Monk tackles a controversial book on the origins of Western civilisation Modern ideals of political freedom, law and critical thinking have their foundations in the Greek and Roman republics. Renaissance and Enlightenment thinkers, from Machiavelli and Montesquieu to Hume, Smith and Gibbon, looked back to an ancient pagan virtue corrupted by empire, then overthrown by barbarism and religion. They sought to recover civic virtue from the feudal and ecclesiastical morass into which, they believed, Europe had descended with the collapse of the Roman Empire. But they saw the empire itself as the beginning of the corruption because it succumbed to oriental despotism and Eastern religion before it fell. As John Pocock reminds us, in his remarkable new study, Barbarism and Religion* (1999), this was the core Enlightenment narrative. If you are a modern rationalist, secularist and democrat (whether liberal or socialist), this is the foundation of your world-view. It is this that has been under attack by Romantics and religious conservatives, deconstructionists, cultural relativists and post-modernists from the 19th century to the present. It is attacked, also, by those who claim that these very Western ideals are the seeds of modern imperialism and "orientalism", in Edward Said's sense. Warwick Ball's new book, Rome in the East: The Transformation of an Empire* requires us to think this through. "We look to Rome for our own European roots," Ball writes. "But Rome itself looked east." True enough: Rome looked to Greece for political, legal and philosophical models. Romans also came to see themselves as descended from the survivors of the sack of Troy. Ball claims a lot more than this, though. It was the very acquisition of the eastern provinces of Asia Minor, Syria, Phoenicia, Judaea and Egypt, he argues, that "led directly to the rise of Rome and of Roman greatness, the first period of greatness in European history". Rome may have civilised the Celtic barbarians of Europe, but it was "on the receiving end of civilisation" in its Asian provinces. Far from Romanising the East, he argues, the Roman Empire witnessed the "triumph of the East". This triumph began with the Romans gradually abandoning their republican institutions and opting for an imperial monarchy in emulation of the Iranian Great Kings. It was manifested by the abandonment of the crude and poor West to the barbarians and the removal of the seat of empire to the East, from the 4th century until the 15th. It was manifested, also, by the rise in Europe itself of Christianity an amalgam of Judaic, Zoroastrian and other Levantine religious cults. Christianity, he writes, was a truly "revolutionary" phenomenon in Europe and it came from Asia. In short, Western civilisation owes its spirit to a fascination with the riches and religions of the East, not to the raw provincialism of the old Romans. Ball's book is a passionate response to Fergus Millar's The Roman Near East 31 BC-AD 337* (1993). Millar asserted rashly that the Romans had found only two cultures in the Near East, the Greek and the Jewish, and put a seal of unity and greatness upon them. This is lambasted by Ball. Millar worked only with Greek and Latin texts, he remarks, but the material evidence tells a very different story. He reminds us that, in Anatolia, Syria, the Levantine coastlands and the Arabian interior, to say nothing of Egypt and Mesopotamia, Rome encountered civilisations that were thousands of years old and which outlasted its domination. This polemical part of the book is strongly argued and beautifully illustrated. It fails, however, to provide a sufficient foundation for Ball's more sweeping argument. His pivotal claim is that the acquisition of the eastern provinces "led directly to the rise of Rome and of Roman greatness, the first period of greatness in European history". It is pivotal for two reasons. It is fundamental to his sustained argument that "the East was the real heart of the Roman Empire" and to his further claim that Western civilisation "as we know it" came out of the East, in the form of Christianity. On the basis of these claims, Ball implicitly overturns traditional Western historiography. His pivotal claim, however, cannot be sustained. Acquisition of the eastern provinces certainly did not lead to the rise of Rome. Rather, the rise of Rome culminated in its acquisition of the eastern provinces. Moreover, "the first period of greatness in European history" has, since classical times, been thought to be the Athenian 5th century BCE. What precipitated that period of greatness was the defeat of the Great Kings of the East by the free Greeks. Finally, while Christianity certainly came from the East, it brooded during the Dark Ages, in Hobbes's famous words, "among the ghosts of the deceased Roman Empire, sitting crowned upon the grave thereof". Catholicism might owe much to the Levant, but it would have lacked its most formidable characteristics had it not draped itself in the mantle of Rome. Above all, it was the recovery and enlargement of the republican and philosophical ideas of Greece and Rome, by thinkers increasingly sceptical of Christianity, that gave modern Western civilisation its defining character. In writing what he has about Rome's rise, Ball disregards even the classical historians in as cavalier a fashion as Millar disregarded the Semitic and Iranian cultures of the Roman East. It would have struck Polybius, for example, as very strange indeed to assert that the acquisition of the eastern provinces "led directly to the rise of Rome". In his 2nd century BCE Universal History, Polybius argued that "in all political situations ... the principal factor which makes for success or failure is the form of a state's constitution: it is from this source, as if from a fountainhead, that all designs and plans of action not only originate but reach their fulfilment". It was the Roman constitution, he believed, that enabled the republic to master the whole Mediterranean world "an event completely without precedent in the past". It was this constitution which Machiavelli, Montesquieu, Gibbon and Mommsen alike, over four centuries of modern historiography, saw as the admirable thing about Rome. Not its empire, but its institutions. Not its riches, but its virtues. What Ball points to as the "triumph of the East", all these thinkers saw as the decadence of the institutions they admired and the failure of the republican virtues to survive the acquisition of the eastern empire. This failure was foreshadowed by Antony's follies in Egypt and came to a head when the very classical-spirited Antonine emperors of the 2nd century CE were succeeded by the Eastern-derived Severan dynasty, at the beginning of the disastrous 3rd century. According to Livy, in the 33rd book of his 1st century BCE History of Rome from its Foundations, when the Romans defeated Philip of Macedon in 197 BCE, they did so in the name of the liberty of the Greek cities. When they then confronted Antiochus the Great heir to both Alexander and the Great Kings of Persia they challenged him, also, in the name of Greek liberty. The Greeks responded with joy that, "There really was a nation on this earth prepared to fight for the freedom of other men, and ... even prepared to cross the sea in order to prevent the establishment of an unjust dominion in any quarter of the globe, and to ensure that right and justice and the rule of law should everywhere be supreme." (How easily Livy could, here, have been an American historian writing in the 1950s or 1960s!). Was this merely the notorious "propaganda of the victors"? No. Their own historians excoriated the crimes and follies of the Romans in the East and in the civil wars that ruined the republic, as have the moderns. Few historical phrases ring more clearly through the annals of Western history than the words Tacitus put into the mouth of a barbarian chieftain. "They (the Romans) make a desert and call it peace." Yet none of those crimes and follies, nor the decline and fall of the empire itself ever obliterated the memory and importance of the institutions and ideals which had been at the foundation of the rise of Rome. Ball, however, seems strangely unacquainted with this whole historiography. His reflections on the architectural wonders of the ancient world aside (for this is his true metier), Ball is at his best in pointing out how vital the commercial networks of the East were, before, during and after Roman domination. He writes of Phoenician commercial penetration of the western Mediterranean, centuries before the rise of Rome. He points to Indian and even Chinese merchants sailing up the Euphrates over many centuries. He argues that the Achaemenid Empire, between the 6th and 4th centuries BCE, was a great cultural bridge between the West and the Indo-Iranian worlds. He observes that "evidence for Palmyrene merchant houses has been found as far apart as Bahrain, the Indus delta, Merv, Rome and Newcastle-upon-Tyne, in England". He is perfectly correct in arguing that all this has a significance which the narrower views of historians like Fergus Millar tend to obscure. In wanting to go further, however, and insist that it was the East that "made" Rome, he overreaches himself. His often vehement argument reminds one of Andre Gunder Frank's passionately anti-Western assertions in ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age* (1998). Frank asserted that, in the second millennium CE, "Europe did not pull itself up by its own economic bootstraps, and certainly not thanks to any kind of European `exceptionalism' of rationality, institutions, entrepreneurship, technology, geniality, in a word of race". Rather, he declares, "Europe climbed up on the back of Asia, then stood on Asian shoulders temporarily". Both authors go astray where Polybius was on the right track. Institutions were in both cases crucial to the Western ascendancy. They are now equally crucial to the future of world order for reasons that have nothing to do with "race". "Pagan architecture," Ball writes, "has ... an arrogant self-confidence, an unquestioning belief in the superiority of its own culture that Christian architecture cannot match ... [late imperial Christian] construction was often second rate, even shoddy." The same, unfortunately, is true of Rome in the East, compared with the great works of Roman history and historiography. For a student of architecture, Ball exhibits a notable lack of architectonic sense in the construction of his argument and an often sloppy lack of attention to detail. He remarks at one point, for example, that "the Parthians had little conception of the Romans as a great power, even less as a civilised one". Yet he later writes that "the Tigris may have been Rome's eastern frontier ... but the presence of so great a power as Rome was felt far beyond". He declares that Roman rule in the East was brutal and exploitative, but elsewhere that "Roman oppression, such as it was, seems to have kept a remarkably low profile". He describes Alexander the Great at Tyre as bringing "Dunsinane Wood to Cawdor" a confused allusion to Shakespeare's Macbeth, in which Birnam Wood is brought to Dunsinane. He confuses, at a crucial point, the 6th century Great King, Khusrau Anurshivan, who fought Emperor Justinian, with the 7th century Khusrau Parviz, who fought Emperor Heraclitus. He describes Constantine as leaving "a crumbling, ramshackle Rome" for the East, but Rome in the early 4th century was very far from being either crumbling or ramshackle and Constantine further embellished it. He declares, at the very end of his narrative, that with Constantine's move to the shores of the Black Sea, "Troy had achieved its greatest triumph." This is vacuous rhetoric. Constantine did not choose Troy. He chose Byzantium. Yet he and all his successors, down to the 15th century, called themselves Roman emperors. The greatest of Ball's solecisms is his failure to acknowledge the modern Western preoccupation with how the classical world lapsed into barbarism and religion. As Nietzsche exclaimed, in Antichrist (1888), "The whole labour of the ancient world in vain: I have no word to express my feelings about something so tremendous ... Wherefore Greeks? Wherefore Romans? All the presuppositions for a scholarly culture, all scientific methods, were already there ... Is this understood? ... the methods, one must say it ten times, are what is essential, also what is most difficult, also what is for the longest time opposed by habits and laziness. What we today have again conquered with immeasurable self-mastery ... had already been there once before". Ball shows no more sense of this than Frank does of the importance of methods and institutions in the modern world. This strange and, I suspect, wilful myopia vitiates their historical and economic arguments. It is not that there is nothing to be said for the deepened perspective on universal history that they demand. On the contrary, such depth is precisely what both classical circumspection and modern enlightenment have been about. It is precisely what inspired Herodotus and Polybius. Ball asserts, however, that the East was the "heart" of the Roman Empire and that Christianity was the triumph of the religion of the East over the provincialism of Rome. In doing this, he behaves like some intellectual Arbogast, blundering into Rome as a would-be ruler without any grasp of what had made the city great. Why does all this matter? Because, at the beginning of the 21st century, the whole human world faces the most profound challenges in consolidating free political institutions, the rule of law and the predominance of critical thinking over dogmatism and superstition. These things were not the fruit of the East, however much cultural relativists and Frankophiles may resent this. They were overwhelmingly the fruit of classical Greco-Roman civilisation and the modern Western enlargement of it. Being in awe of Eastern temple ruins or palaces, like Ball, or of the ill-fated splendours of old China and India, like Frank, risks blinding one to this reality. When Montesquieu wrote his great 18th-century treatise on the spirit of law, he did so with critical reflection on Chinese, Persian and Byzantine despotism in mind, but the Greek and Roman republican constitutions as a beacon. If, nearly 400 years after Montesquieu, we seek to enlarge the sway of the spirit of law in the world, then in irreducibly important ways, we must start with the problem of Rome in the East. If our reflections on this problem lead us only, with Warwick Ball, to the conclusion that Rome was "on the receiving end of civilisation" in the East, we may well fail to find any basis on which to extend political freedom and the rule of law in the emerging global culture. For it is neither Eastern despotism nor Eastern religion that we are in need of. It is civic virtue and those "methods" to which Nietzsche referred, in 1888. It is what he lauded as "the free eye before reality, the cautious hand, patience and seriousness ... the whole integrity in knowledge". It is enlightened classical virtues that we need. The challenge is how to engender and sustain them in a crowded and turbulent world. *Barbarism and Religion. By John Pocock. Cambridge University Press. $75. Rome in the East: The Transformation of an Empire. By Warwick Ball. 523pp. Routledge. $63.80. The Roman Near East: 31BC-AD337. By Fergus Millar. Harvard University Press. $35.20. ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. By Andre Gunder Frank. California University Press. $55. Copyright John Fairfax Holdings Limited 2001. Not available for re-dissemination. Quellen:AUSTRALIAN FINANCIAL REVIEW 11/05/2001 P6 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 02Mär2001 INDIA: Marx and globalisation - II. By Gail Omvedt. FROM THE 1950s onwards, most of the newly-independent colonies and dependencies switched to policies of protectionism, disengagement from the world market and heavy state controls, including nationalisation of basic industries and planning. India's "Nehru model" was only one example of this process. The suspicion of capitalism and the market was quite understandable. Unbridled free market capitalism had resulted in unprecedented economic crisis with the Great Depression of the 1930s followed by war and turmoil throughout the world, and capitalist countries themselves had responded with a move to planning and state controls, including the "New Deal" in the United States. The evident success of early Soviet industrial development and opposition to the imperialist world was also inspiring to many poor countries and supported an upsurge in marxist ideology and socialist trends throughout the world. Marxists themselves turned away from the idea that countries had to go through a stage of capitalism. Those who supported protectionism and withdrawal from the world market became known as "dependency theorists". All social science theories recognised the problems of industrialism along with its unprecedented growth, but they fell into two trends in explaining how growth took place and how it could spread. The dominant "modernisation theories" emphasised internal factors; capitalism, it was argued, could develop in the West because of inherent values supporting individualism, accumulation and technological innovation, and could spread to non-Western countries as well if existing barriers of feudal values and social relations could be overcome. Trade and exchange of ideas were seen as engines of growth, while the more ethnocentric sociologists emphasised the supposed "backwardness" of many non-Western cultural systems as the major factors in holding back change. In contrast, dependency theorists argued that economic growth in the West had been based on imperialist exploitation, and that the very success of developed countries was at the cost of the misery and continued backwardness of others. In the words of one of the most famous of these, Andre Gunder Frank, it was said that "development creates underdevelopment". Not only forms of direct colonisation, but trade itself was seen as keeping the poorer countries backward. Thus dependency theorists recommended not only state controls and nationalisation as steps towards socialism, but also protectionism, autarchy and withdrawal from market forces as necessary to "independent capitalistic development". In fact, Marx himself was a modernisation theorist of a very particular type. Unlike those economists and sociologists who saw the process as harmonious, Marx viewed the historical process as one of contradiction and exploitation; unlike conventional social scientists he did not see it as ending with capitalism. With all of this, though, he still believed that capitalism produced growth, that this was transmitted through market relations and foreign investment, and that there was no road directly from feudalism to socialism. Thus dependency theorists, though calling themselves Marxists, were rejecting crucial themes of Marx himself, and found their social base in the intellectuals and nationalist elites of the third world rather than in working class movements. In this sense, they were "revisionists". There is nothing, of course, wrong with "revisionism"; sciences, unlike dogmas, progress through engagement with the changing real world and through developing and revising their hypotheses and theories. But in this respect, Marx seems to have been more correct than his dependency theory followers of the current period. If we look at the broad paradigms of modernisation theory and dependency theory simply in terms of the predictions about increasing inequality, it is clear that from 1800 to the 1960s or so - the classic period of imperialism and colonialism - economic social inequalities increased dramatically throughout the world. In this sense, dependency theory was correct: industrialisation did have internal sources of dynamism, but its effect throughout the world was to increase inequality and exploitation, to extract resources from the third world for the development of capitalism in the West. From the 1960s onwards, however, the picture is different. Economic inequalites (though these are hard to measure, given problems of exchange rates) have remained in many respects; however, there are two counter trends. First, according to the Human Development Reports, as measured in terms of most material indicators, such as calories of food available per capita, maternal mortality rates, child mortality rates, life spans etc., the gap between the North and the South has on the whole declined, not increased. During the "decade of globalisation" in the 1990s almost all countries, with the notable exception of the former Soviet bloc, improved in terms of human development. Further, during the 1990s, the share of the U.S. in world GDP increased marginally from 26 per cent to 28.8 per cent (after declining from over a third of the world total in the 1960s), but the share of China increased from 1.6 per cent to 3.3 per cent, the share of East and South East Asian developing countries as a whole increased from 4.3 to 6.2 per cent, while India's share increased marginally from 1.1 to 1.5 per cent. Developing countries, especially those in Asia and Latin America, have moved from dependence on agricultural, mineral and oil production and exports fostered by the colonial regime to increasingly sophisticated manufactured goods. Dependency theorists have partly recognised this by talking of "dependent development", but this would have been a rather meaningless category for Marx, who spoke from the viewpoint of the working class for whom the crucial factor was overall development and the increase in capacities of the majority of toilers in a country, not the skin colour of the capitalists; the ability of Asian and Latin American capitalists to gain a role in the world industrial hierarchy would not have been a major criterion for him. It is also undeniable that there have been dramatic differences among the growth rates and poverty reduction achievements of different third world countries. Generally speaking (except for the crisis in the former Soviet bloc, which has its own dynamic), those countries most marginalised in terms of the world market - including most of the African countries - grew the slowest and remained poorest. Those which engaged intelligently with the world market, for instance with policies of export orientation, grew. South Asian countries such as India had some of the highest degrees of state involvement in production and in regulating the market forces and at the same time had among the slowest growth rates. In China also, the communist period could produce an equalitarian spread of education and health, but it was only after economic reforms began in 1978 that rapid economic growth took place. Today many Chinese see the state sector as providing stability, while the private, capitalistic sector is the engine of growth. Marx himself would not have disagreed. Capitalism to him meant not simply exploitation, which has existed in all pre-capitalist class societies, but specifically the rapid advancement of the forces of production, the overturning of old ways of life and the increasing integration of the world - all factors he saw not as negative, but as laying the basis for socialism. While those speaking in his name today are taking opposition to "liberalisation, privatisation and globalisation" as a simple slogan, Marx himself would have looked to the ways the new developments in capitalist, science-based information technology and biotechnolo-gies provide both opportunities for growth in welfare and the liberation of the masses of working people and the basis for using the contradictions they represent for moving towards socialism. If the old ways of trying to build socialism have seemingly failed, people themselves through their movements will find out the new ways on the basis of the reality of the world today. (Concluded). (c) 2001 Katsuri & Sons Ltd. Quellen:THE HINDU 02/03/2001 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 28Dez2000 JAPAN: THE STATESMAN (INDIA) - COLUMN ONE - DEPENDENCY THEORY-I - History's Verdict Against It. By SUSHILA RAMASWAMY. IN the immediate aftermath of World War II, as a consequence of decolonisation, many new nations emerged and became full-fledged sovereign members of the world community. Their utmost consideration was economic development, eradicating poverty and raising the standards of living of their people. They understood that political independence alone was not enough unless they could achieve economic power and self-reliance. They carved out a distinct place in the world and styled themselves as the Third World with a definitive ideology that provided a radical critique of existing world order, one marked by sharp inequities and disparities. They questioned the rationale for their poverty and backwardness, which was in sharp contrast to the affluence of Europe, North America and Japan. Their emphasis was on the role of governments and controlling markets to bring about accelerated national economic growth. To find a solution to this problem many intellectuals began to question the proposition of classical economists like Adam Smith and Ricardo that growth in free world trading would abolish poverty and backwardness. There were two basic objections to this proposition. First that poverty was not inevitable and second, world market in itself was not adequate to tackle it. Governments in the developed countries played a central role by regularly intervening and regulating the market. NEOCOLONIALISM Raul Prebisch understood that the 19th century paradigm of free trade was inoperative and disadvantageous to these new raw materials exporting nations in the middle of 20th century. He stressed a solution that had both national and international ramifications. Internationally the centre ought to help the peripheries through foreign aid and technical assistance. It ought to give special treatment to raw materials exporting countries and aid the third world governments trying to reform domestic industry till a point when the nation consumed its own locally produced manufactured goods irrespective of the costs. Such an effort at import substitution would lessen dependence on imports and reduce the need to export simultaneously increasing domestic employment and income. This would result in an expanded domestic market accelerating the process of industrialisation. The dependency theory was Marxist in orientation but intellectually drew its sustenance from the non-Marxist analysis of Prebisch. It originated among the radical social scientists of Latin America. Using the Latin American experiences they developed their formulations. By giving a twist in the neo-Marxist direction to Prebisch's formulations dependency theory became a critique of the modernisation theory. Moderni-sation theory combining economic, psychological and sociological factors understood modernity to include value systems, individual motivation and capital accumulation. It emphasised considerably the role values, norms and belief-structures played in the transformation of a traditional society into a modern one. Dependency theorists rejected the modernisation theories both with regard to analysis and prediction. They associated under-development to the linkage under-developed countries had with the developed countries. Unlike Prebisch who suggested remedies both national and international, the depen-dency theorists analysed the problem of under-development within the framework of international structures and pro-cess. They followed the Leni-nist legacy of Marxism and connect the continued impoverishment and under-development of the periphery to the sustained unequal exchange with the developed West. While Lenin regarded imperialism as the last stage of capitalism the dependency theorists gloomily considered imperialism as the basis of perpetuating inequality and dependency. Unlike the development theorist for whom domestic factors were crucial to explaining poverty and backwardness the dependency theorists attributed the poverty of the poor countries to the affluence of and exploitation by the rich ones. They pointed to historical antecedents when the colonial powers deliberately thwarted the indigenous development of their colonies. For most of the newly independent countries political freedom remained meaningless since advanced countries through multinational corporations, foreign aid and technological and cultural dependence economically dominated them. This was established and perpetuated through a policy of collaboration bet-ween foreign and local capital with the help of the support base of a new class. GRAND NARRATIVE Andre Gunder Frank developed dependency theory into a grand one by emphasising the intrinsic link between under development and dependency with globalisation of capitalism. The dependency theorists contended that the distinction between un-development and underdevelopment was due to the mercantilist and capitalist expansion of the European powers. What followed was a unity of interests among the developed countries while the under-developed regions re-mained disunited. Since then the unequal relationship bet-ween the developed and underdeveloped regions continued with calamitous consequences for the latter. The dependency theorists located the problem of under-development in the very nature of contemporary capitalism and recommended the erstwhile Soviet model of industrialisation, in which the state rather than the consumer decided priorities as the only way out of the limitations of bourgeois reforms. A leap towards socialism would guarantee both a balanced growth and total national control over production and allocation of its resultant surplus. However they ignored one important historical fact that the socialist countries in the developing world suffered as much from the phenomenon of dependency as their own non-socialist counterparts. A good example was Cuba whose economy was paralysed and dependent on subsidy from the former Soviet Union to the tune of four billion dollars a year, half of Cuba's national income. Both Ethiopia and Vietnam in the early 80's faced virtual famines and had to be helped by the West to tide over the crisis. The Communist nations in the developing world were as much dependent on the developed socialist countries, as were the non-communist ones on advanced capitalist countries. The crux of the argument of the dependency theorists was that countries with a high deg-ree of dependency would have very low rates of economic growth. The growth rate in the satellites would be highest when their link with the centre is at the weakest. For instance Frank cited the examples of the two World Wars and the period of the Great Depression when the Latin American economies did very well. Another caveat of the argument was that within the dual economy an augmented foreign investment led to greater inequality in incomes and attenuated foreign indebtedness. Dependency theorists dismissed the argument of the conventional economists that foreign trade and capital could be beneficial. However they did not satisfactorily deal with the problem of isolationism. GROSS FALLACIES The erstwhile socialist society pursued an isolationist economic policy with aims of self-sufficiency and independent development as demonstrated by the fact that they produced little less than 25 per cent of World GNP yet their share of world exports were merely 14 per cent. This also meant that they were out of the prevailing trend towards internationalisation of the production process and membership of financial institutions. The exclusiveness meant that the three important components of modern business organisation, increased efficiency, product quality and consumer choice did not be-come a part of their economic processes. In not dealing with these important issues the dependency theory ignored some of the very key issues of modern organisational structure and the role of scientific and technological innovations and in that sense is pre-modern. In course of testing the hypothesis of the dependency theory in the context of Latin America Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller took into account the relationship between the dependency economies and economic growth. They incorporated variables like degree of trade partner concentration, degree of concentration of commodities and flow of foreign capital and investment and found gross fallacies in the dependency theory. The majority of indicators pointed to the fact that the more dependent countries grew faster rather than slowly as contended by the dependency theorists. This was important for it falsified one of their core assumptions about dependency and economic growth. Furthermore, Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller also established the fact that though dependency produced income inequality yet there was a strong negative link between dependency and land inequality, disproving another major contention of the dependency theorists. (To be concluded) All Material Subject to Copyright Copyright 2000: The Statesman (India). All Rights Reserved. Quellen:ASIA INTELLIGENCE WIRE THE STATESMAN 28/12/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 28Dez2000 JAPAN: THE STATESMAN (INDIA) - COLUMN ONE - DEPENDENCY THEORY-I - History's Verdict Against It. By SUSHILA RAMASWAMY. IN the immediate aftermath of World War II, as a consequence of decolonisation, many new nations emerged and became full-fledged sovereign members of the world community. Their utmost consideration was economic development, eradicating poverty and raising the standards of living of their people. They understood that political independence alone was not enough unless they could achieve economic power and self-reliance. They carved out a distinct place in the world and styled themselves as the Third World with a definitive ideology that provided a radical critique of existing world order, one marked by sharp inequities and disparities. They questioned the rationale for their poverty and backwardness, which was in sharp contrast to the affluence of Europe, North America and Japan. Their emphasis was on the role of governments and controlling markets to bring about accelerated national economic growth. To find a solution to this problem many intellectuals began to question the proposition of classical economists like Adam Smith and Ricardo that growth in free world trading would abolish poverty and backwardness. There were two basic objections to this proposition. First that poverty was not inevitable and second, world market in itself was not adequate to tackle it. Governments in the developed countries played a central role by regularly intervening and regulating the market. NEOCOLONIALISM Raul Prebisch understood that the 19th century paradigm of free trade was inoperative and disadvantageous to these new raw materials exporting nations in the middle of 20th century. He stressed a solution that had both national and international ramifications. Internationally the centre ought to help the peripheries through foreign aid and technical assistance. It ought to give special treatment to raw materials exporting countries and aid the third world governments trying to reform domestic industry till a point when the nation consumed its own locally produced manufactured goods irrespective of the costs. Such an effort at import substitution would lessen dependence on imports and reduce the need to export simultaneously increasing domestic employment and income. This would result in an expanded domestic market accelerating the process of industrialisation. The dependency theory was Marxist in orientation but intellectually drew its sustenance from the non-Marxist analysis of Prebisch. It originated among the radical social scientists of Latin America. Using the Latin American experiences they developed their formulations. By giving a twist in the neo-Marxist direction to Prebisch's formulations dependency theory became a critique of the modernisation theory. Moderni-sation theory combining economic, psychological and sociological factors understood modernity to include value systems, individual motivation and capital accumulation. It emphasised considerably the role values, norms and belief-structures played in the transformation of a traditional society into a modern one. Dependency theorists rejected the modernisation theories both with regard to analysis and prediction. They associated under-development to the linkage under-developed countries had with the developed countries. Unlike Prebisch who suggested remedies both national and international, the depen-dency theorists analysed the problem of under-development within the framework of international structures and pro-cess. They followed the Leni-nist legacy of Marxism and connect the continued impoverishment and under-development of the periphery to the sustained unequal exchange with the developed West. While Lenin regarded imperialism as the last stage of capitalism the dependency theorists gloomily considered imperialism as the basis of perpetuating inequality and dependency. Unlike the development theorist for whom domestic factors were crucial to explaining poverty and backwardness the dependency theorists attributed the poverty of the poor countries to the affluence of and exploitation by the rich ones. They pointed to historical antecedents when the colonial powers deliberately thwarted the indigenous development of their colonies. For most of the newly independent countries political freedom remained meaningless since advanced countries through multinational corporations, foreign aid and technological and cultural dependence economically dominated them. This was established and perpetuated through a policy of collaboration bet-ween foreign and local capital with the help of the support base of a new class. GRAND NARRATIVE Andre Gunder Frank developed dependency theory into a grand one by emphasising the intrinsic link between under development and dependency with globalisation of capitalism. The dependency theorists contended that the distinction between un-development and underdevelopment was due to the mercantilist and capitalist expansion of the European powers. What followed was a unity of interests among the developed countries while the under-developed regions re-mained disunited. Since then the unequal relationship bet-ween the developed and underdeveloped regions continued with calamitous consequences for the latter. The dependency theorists located the problem of under-development in the very nature of contemporary capitalism and recommended the erstwhile Soviet model of industrialisation, in which the state rather than the consumer decided priorities as the only way out of the limitations of bourgeois reforms. A leap towards socialism would guarantee both a balanced growth and total national control over production and allocation of its resultant surplus. However they ignored one important historical fact that the socialist countries in the developing world suffered as much from the phenomenon of dependency as their own non-socialist counterparts. A good example was Cuba whose economy was paralysed and dependent on subsidy from the former Soviet Union to the tune of four billion dollars a year, half of Cuba's national income. Both Ethiopia and Vietnam in the early 80's faced virtual famines and had to be helped by the West to tide over the crisis. The Communist nations in the developing world were as much dependent on the developed socialist countries, as were the non-communist ones on advanced capitalist countries. The crux of the argument of the dependency theorists was that countries with a high deg-ree of dependency would have very low rates of economic growth. The growth rate in the satellites would be highest when their link with the centre is at the weakest. For instance Frank cited the examples of the two World Wars and the period of the Great Depression when the Latin American economies did very well. Another caveat of the argument was that within the dual economy an augmented foreign investment led to greater inequality in incomes and attenuated foreign indebtedness. Dependency theorists dismissed the argument of the conventional economists that foreign trade and capital could be beneficial. However they did not satisfactorily deal with the problem of isolationism. GROSS FALLACIES The erstwhile socialist society pursued an isolationist economic policy with aims of self-sufficiency and independent development as demonstrated by the fact that they produced little less than 25 per cent of World GNP yet their share of world exports were merely 14 per cent. This also meant that they were out of the prevailing trend towards internationalisation of the production process and membership of financial institutions. The exclusiveness meant that the three important components of modern business organisation, increased efficiency, product quality and consumer choice did not be-come a part of their economic processes. In not dealing with these important issues the dependency theory ignored some of the very key issues of modern organisational structure and the role of scientific and technological innovations and in that sense is pre-modern. In course of testing the hypothesis of the dependency theory in the context of Latin America Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller took into account the relationship between the dependency economies and economic growth. They incorporated variables like degree of trade partner concentration, degree of concentration of commodities and flow of foreign capital and investment and found gross fallacies in the dependency theory. The majority of indicators pointed to the fact that the more dependent countries grew faster rather than slowly as contended by the dependency theorists. This was important for it falsified one of their core assumptions about dependency and economic growth. Furthermore, Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller also established the fact that though dependency produced income inequality yet there was a strong negative link between dependency and land inequality, disproving another major contention of the dependency theorists. (To be concluded) All Material Subject to Copyright Copyright 2000: The Statesman (India). All Rights Reserved. Quellen:ASIA INTELLIGENCE WIRE THE STATESMAN 28/12/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 28Dez2000 JAPAN: THE STATESMAN (INDIA) - COLUMN ONE - DEPENDENCY THEORY-I - History's Verdict Against It. By SUSHILA RAMASWAMY. IN the immediate aftermath of World War II, as a consequence of decolonisation, many new nations emerged and became full-fledged sovereign members of the world community. Their utmost consideration was economic development, eradicating poverty and raising the standards of living of their people. They understood that political independence alone was not enough unless they could achieve economic power and self-reliance. They carved out a distinct place in the world and styled themselves as the Third World with a definitive ideology that provided a radical critique of existing world order, one marked by sharp inequities and disparities. They questioned the rationale for their poverty and backwardness, which was in sharp contrast to the affluence of Europe, North America and Japan. Their emphasis was on the role of governments and controlling markets to bring about accelerated national economic growth. To find a solution to this problem many intellectuals began to question the proposition of classical economists like Adam Smith and Ricardo that growth in free world trading would abolish poverty and backwardness. There were two basic objections to this proposition. First that poverty was not inevitable and second, world market in itself was not adequate to tackle it. Governments in the developed countries played a central role by regularly intervening and regulating the market. NEOCOLONIALISM Raul Prebisch understood that the 19th century paradigm of free trade was inoperative and disadvantageous to these new raw materials exporting nations in the middle of 20th century. He stressed a solution that had both national and international ramifications. Internationally the centre ought to help the peripheries through foreign aid and technical assistance. It ought to give special treatment to raw materials exporting countries and aid the third world governments trying to reform domestic industry till a point when the nation consumed its own locally produced manufactured goods irrespective of the costs. Such an effort at import substitution would lessen dependence on imports and reduce the need to export simultaneously increasing domestic employment and income. This would result in an expanded domestic market accelerating the process of industrialisation. The dependency theory was Marxist in orientation but intellectually drew its sustenance from the non-Marxist analysis of Prebisch. It originated among the radical social scientists of Latin America. Using the Latin American experiences they developed their formulations. By giving a twist in the neo-Marxist direction to Prebisch's formulations dependency theory became a critique of the modernisation theory. Moderni-sation theory combining economic, psychological and sociological factors understood modernity to include value systems, individual motivation and capital accumulation. It emphasised considerably the role values, norms and belief-structures played in the transformation of a traditional society into a modern one. Dependency theorists rejected the modernisation theories both with regard to analysis and prediction. They associated under-development to the linkage under-developed countries had with the developed countries. Unlike Prebisch who suggested remedies both national and international, the depen-dency theorists analysed the problem of under-development within the framework of international structures and pro-cess. They followed the Leni-nist legacy of Marxism and connect the continued impoverishment and under-development of the periphery to the sustained unequal exchange with the developed West. While Lenin regarded imperialism as the last stage of capitalism the dependency theorists gloomily considered imperialism as the basis of perpetuating inequality and dependency. Unlike the development theorist for whom domestic factors were crucial to explaining poverty and backwardness the dependency theorists attributed the poverty of the poor countries to the affluence of and exploitation by the rich ones. They pointed to historical antecedents when the colonial powers deliberately thwarted the indigenous development of their colonies. For most of the newly independent countries political freedom remained meaningless since advanced countries through multinational corporations, foreign aid and technological and cultural dependence economically dominated them. This was established and perpetuated through a policy of collaboration bet-ween foreign and local capital with the help of the support base of a new class. GRAND NARRATIVE Andre Gunder Frank developed dependency theory into a grand one by emphasising the intrinsic link between under development and dependency with globalisation of capitalism. The dependency theorists contended that the distinction between un-development and underdevelopment was due to the mercantilist and capitalist expansion of the European powers. What followed was a unity of interests among the developed countries while the under-developed regions re-mained disunited. Since then the unequal relationship bet-ween the developed and underdeveloped regions continued with calamitous consequences for the latter. The dependency theorists located the problem of under-development in the very nature of contemporary capitalism and recommended the erstwhile Soviet model of industrialisation, in which the state rather than the consumer decided priorities as the only way out of the limitations of bourgeois reforms. A leap towards socialism would guarantee both a balanced growth and total national control over production and allocation of its resultant surplus. However they ignored one important historical fact that the socialist countries in the developing world suffered as much from the phenomenon of dependency as their own non-socialist counterparts. A good example was Cuba whose economy was paralysed and dependent on subsidy from the former Soviet Union to the tune of four billion dollars a year, half of Cuba's national income. Both Ethiopia and Vietnam in the early 80's faced virtual famines and had to be helped by the West to tide over the crisis. The Communist nations in the developing world were as much dependent on the developed socialist countries, as were the non-communist ones on advanced capitalist countries. The crux of the argument of the dependency theorists was that countries with a high deg-ree of dependency would have very low rates of economic growth. The growth rate in the satellites would be highest when their link with the centre is at the weakest. For instance Frank cited the examples of the two World Wars and the period of the Great Depression when the Latin American economies did very well. Another caveat of the argument was that within the dual economy an augmented foreign investment led to greater inequality in incomes and attenuated foreign indebtedness. Dependency theorists dismissed the argument of the conventional economists that foreign trade and capital could be beneficial. However they did not satisfactorily deal with the problem of isolationism. GROSS FALLACIES The erstwhile socialist society pursued an isolationist economic policy with aims of self-sufficiency and independent development as demonstrated by the fact that they produced little less than 25 per cent of World GNP yet their share of world exports were merely 14 per cent. This also meant that they were out of the prevailing trend towards internationalisation of the production process and membership of financial institutions. The exclusiveness meant that the three important components of modern business organisation, increased efficiency, product quality and consumer choice did not be-come a part of their economic processes. In not dealing with these important issues the dependency theory ignored some of the very key issues of modern organisational structure and the role of scientific and technological innovations and in that sense is pre-modern. In course of testing the hypothesis of the dependency theory in the context of Latin America Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller took into account the relationship between the dependency economies and economic growth. They incorporated variables like degree of trade partner concentration, degree of concentration of commodities and flow of foreign capital and investment and found gross fallacies in the dependency theory. The majority of indicators pointed to the fact that the more dependent countries grew faster rather than slowly as contended by the dependency theorists. This was important for it falsified one of their core assumptions about dependency and economic growth. Furthermore, Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller also established the fact that though dependency produced income inequality yet there was a strong negative link between dependency and land inequality, disproving another major contention of the dependency theorists. (To be concluded) All Material Subject to Copyright Copyright 2000: The Statesman (India). All Rights Reserved. Quellen:ASIA INTELLIGENCE WIRE THE STATESMAN 28/12/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 28Dez2000 JAPAN: THE STATESMAN (INDIA) - COLUMN ONE - DEPENDENCY THEORY-I - History's Verdict Against It. By SUSHILA RAMASWAMY. IN the immediate aftermath of World War II, as a consequence of decolonisation, many new nations emerged and became full-fledged sovereign members of the world community. Their utmost consideration was economic development, eradicating poverty and raising the standards of living of their people. They understood that political independence alone was not enough unless they could achieve economic power and self-reliance. They carved out a distinct place in the world and styled themselves as the Third World with a definitive ideology that provided a radical critique of existing world order, one marked by sharp inequities and disparities. They questioned the rationale for their poverty and backwardness, which was in sharp contrast to the affluence of Europe, North America and Japan. Their emphasis was on the role of governments and controlling markets to bring about accelerated national economic growth. To find a solution to this problem many intellectuals began to question the proposition of classical economists like Adam Smith and Ricardo that growth in free world trading would abolish poverty and backwardness. There were two basic objections to this proposition. First that poverty was not inevitable and second, world market in itself was not adequate to tackle it. Governments in the developed countries played a central role by regularly intervening and regulating the market. NEOCOLONIALISM Raul Prebisch understood that the 19th century paradigm of free trade was inoperative and disadvantageous to these new raw materials exporting nations in the middle of 20th century. He stressed a solution that had both national and international ramifications. Internationally the centre ought to help the peripheries through foreign aid and technical assistance. It ought to give special treatment to raw materials exporting countries and aid the third world governments trying to reform domestic industry till a point when the nation consumed its own locally produced manufactured goods irrespective of the costs. Such an effort at import substitution would lessen dependence on imports and reduce the need to export simultaneously increasing domestic employment and income. This would result in an expanded domestic market accelerating the process of industrialisation. The dependency theory was Marxist in orientation but intellectually drew its sustenance from the non-Marxist analysis of Prebisch. It originated among the radical social scientists of Latin America. Using the Latin American experiences they developed their formulations. By giving a twist in the neo-Marxist direction to Prebisch's formulations dependency theory became a critique of the modernisation theory. Moderni-sation theory combining economic, psychological and sociological factors understood modernity to include value systems, individual motivation and capital accumulation. It emphasised considerably the role values, norms and belief-structures played in the transformation of a traditional society into a modern one. Dependency theorists rejected the modernisation theories both with regard to analysis and prediction. They associated under-development to the linkage under-developed countries had with the developed countries. Unlike Prebisch who suggested remedies both national and international, the depen-dency theorists analysed the problem of under-development within the framework of international structures and pro-cess. They followed the Leni-nist legacy of Marxism and connect the continued impoverishment and under-development of the periphery to the sustained unequal exchange with the developed West. While Lenin regarded imperialism as the last stage of capitalism the dependency theorists gloomily considered imperialism as the basis of perpetuating inequality and dependency. Unlike the development theorist for whom domestic factors were crucial to explaining poverty and backwardness the dependency theorists attributed the poverty of the poor countries to the affluence of and exploitation by the rich ones. They pointed to historical antecedents when the colonial powers deliberately thwarted the indigenous development of their colonies. For most of the newly independent countries political freedom remained meaningless since advanced countries through multinational corporations, foreign aid and technological and cultural dependence economically dominated them. This was established and perpetuated through a policy of collaboration bet-ween foreign and local capital with the help of the support base of a new class. GRAND NARRATIVE Andre Gunder Frank developed dependency theory into a grand one by emphasising the intrinsic link between under development and dependency with globalisation of capitalism. The dependency theorists contended that the distinction between un-development and underdevelopment was due to the mercantilist and capitalist expansion of the European powers. What followed was a unity of interests among the developed countries while the under-developed regions re-mained disunited. Since then the unequal relationship bet-ween the developed and underdeveloped regions continued with calamitous consequences for the latter. The dependency theorists located the problem of under-development in the very nature of contemporary capitalism and recommended the erstwhile Soviet model of industrialisation, in which the state rather than the consumer decided priorities as the only way out of the limitations of bourgeois reforms. A leap towards socialism would guarantee both a balanced growth and total national control over production and allocation of its resultant surplus. However they ignored one important historical fact that the socialist countries in the developing world suffered as much from the phenomenon of dependency as their own non-socialist counterparts. A good example was Cuba whose economy was paralysed and dependent on subsidy from the former Soviet Union to the tune of four billion dollars a year, half of Cuba's national income. Both Ethiopia and Vietnam in the early 80's faced virtual famines and had to be helped by the West to tide over the crisis. The Communist nations in the developing world were as much dependent on the developed socialist countries, as were the non-communist ones on advanced capitalist countries. The crux of the argument of the dependency theorists was that countries with a high deg-ree of dependency would have very low rates of economic growth. The growth rate in the satellites would be highest when their link with the centre is at the weakest. For instance Frank cited the examples of the two World Wars and the period of the Great Depression when the Latin American economies did very well. Another caveat of the argument was that within the dual economy an augmented foreign investment led to greater inequality in incomes and attenuated foreign indebtedness. Dependency theorists dismissed the argument of the conventional economists that foreign trade and capital could be beneficial. However they did not satisfactorily deal with the problem of isolationism. GROSS FALLACIES The erstwhile socialist society pursued an isolationist economic policy with aims of self-sufficiency and independent development as demonstrated by the fact that they produced little less than 25 per cent of World GNP yet their share of world exports were merely 14 per cent. This also meant that they were out of the prevailing trend towards internationalisation of the production process and membership of financial institutions. The exclusiveness meant that the three important components of modern business organisation, increased efficiency, product quality and consumer choice did not be-come a part of their economic processes. In not dealing with these important issues the dependency theory ignored some of the very key issues of modern organisational structure and the role of scientific and technological innovations and in that sense is pre-modern. In course of testing the hypothesis of the dependency theory in the context of Latin America Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller took into account the relationship between the dependency economies and economic growth. They incorporated variables like degree of trade partner concentration, degree of concentration of commodities and flow of foreign capital and investment and found gross fallacies in the dependency theory. The majority of indicators pointed to the fact that the more dependent countries grew faster rather than slowly as contended by the dependency theorists. This was important for it falsified one of their core assumptions about dependency and economic growth. Furthermore, Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller also established the fact that though dependency produced income inequality yet there was a strong negative link between dependency and land inequality, disproving another major contention of the dependency theorists. (To be concluded) All Material Subject to Copyright Copyright 2000: The Statesman (India). All Rights Reserved. Quellen:ASIA INTELLIGENCE WIRE THE STATESMAN 28/12/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 27Dez2000 JAPAN: THE STATESMAN (INDIA) - COLUMN ONE - DEPENDENCY THEORY-I - History's Verdict Against It. By SUSHILA RAMASWAMY. IN the immediate aftermath of World War II, as a consequence of decolonisation, many new nations emerged and became full-fledged sovereign members of the world community. Their utmost consideration was economic development, eradicating poverty and raising the standards of living of their people. They understood that political independence alone was not enough unless they could achieve economic power and self-reliance. They carved out a distinct place in the world and styled themselves as the Third World with a definitive ideology that provided a radical critique of existing world order, one marked by sharp inequities and disparities. They questioned the rationale for their poverty and backwardness, which was in sharp contrast to the affluence of Europe, North America and Japan. Their emphasis was on the role of governments and controlling markets to bring about accelerated national economic growth. To find a solution to this problem many intellectuals began to question the proposition of classical economists like Adam Smith and Ricardo that growth in free world trading would abolish poverty and backwardness. There were two basic objections to this proposition. First that poverty was not inevitable and second, world market in itself was not adequate to tackle it. Governments in the developed countries played a central role by regularly intervening and regulating the market. NEOCOLONIALISM Raul Prebisch understood that the 19th century paradigm of free trade was inoperative and disadvantageous to these new raw materials exporting nations in the middle of 20th century. He stressed a solution that had both national and international ramifications. Internationally the centre ought to help the peripheries through foreign aid and technical assistance. It ought to give special treatment to raw materials exporting countries and aid the third world governments trying to reform domestic industry till a point when the nation consumed its own locally produced manufactured goods irrespective of the costs. Such an effort at import substitution would lessen dependence on imports and reduce the need to export simultaneously increasing domestic employment and income. This would result in an expanded domestic market accelerating the process of industrialisation. The dependency theory was Marxist in orientation but intellectually drew its sustenance from the non-Marxist analysis of Prebisch. It originated among the radical social scientists of Latin America. Using the Latin American experiences they developed their formulations. By giving a twist in the neo-Marxist direction to Prebisch's formulations dependency theory became a critique of the modernisation theory. Moderni-sation theory combining economic, psychological and sociological factors understood modernity to include value systems, individual motivation and capital accumulation. It emphasised considerably the role values, norms and belief-structures played in the transformation of a traditional society into a modern one. Dependency theorists rejected the modernisation theories both with regard to analysis and prediction. They associated under-development to the linkage under-developed countries had with the developed countries. Unlike Prebisch who suggested remedies both national and international, the depen-dency theorists analysed the problem of under-development within the framework of international structures and pro-cess. They followed the Leni-nist legacy of Marxism and connect the continued impoverishment and under-development of the periphery to the sustained unequal exchange with the developed West. While Lenin regarded imperialism as the last stage of capitalism the dependency theorists gloomily considered imperialism as the basis of perpetuating inequality and dependency. Unlike the development theorist for whom domestic factors were crucial to explaining poverty and backwardness the dependency theorists attributed the poverty of the poor countries to the affluence of and exploitation by the rich ones. They pointed to historical antecedents when the colonial powers deliberately thwarted the indigenous development of their colonies. For most of the newly independent countries political freedom remained meaningless since advanced countries through multinational corporations, foreign aid and technological and cultural dependence economically dominated them. This was established and perpetuated through a policy of collaboration bet-ween foreign and local capital with the help of the support base of a new class. GRAND NARRATIVE Andre Gunder Frank developed dependency theory into a grand one by emphasising the intrinsic link between under development and dependency with globalisation of capitalism. The dependency theorists contended that the distinction between un-development and underdevelopment was due to the mercantilist and capitalist expansion of the European powers. What followed was a unity of interests among the developed countries while the under-developed regions re-mained disunited. Since then the unequal relationship bet-ween the developed and underdeveloped regions continued with calamitous consequences for the latter. The dependency theorists located the problem of under-development in the very nature of contemporary capitalism and recommended the erstwhile Soviet model of industrialisation, in which the state rather than the consumer decided priorities as the only way out of the limitations of bourgeois reforms. A leap towards socialism would guarantee both a balanced growth and total national control over production and allocation of its resultant surplus. However they ignored one important historical fact that the socialist countries in the developing world suffered as much from the phenomenon of dependency as their own non-socialist counterparts. A good example was Cuba whose economy was paralysed and dependent on subsidy from the former Soviet Union to the tune of four billion dollars a year, half of Cuba's national income. Both Ethiopia and Vietnam in the early 80's faced virtual famines and had to be helped by the West to tide over the crisis. The Communist nations in the developing world were as much dependent on the developed socialist countries, as were the non-communist ones on advanced capitalist countries. The crux of the argument of the dependency theorists was that countries with a high deg-ree of dependency would have very low rates of economic growth. The growth rate in the satellites would be highest when their link with the centre is at the weakest. For instance Frank cited the examples of the two World Wars and the period of the Great Depression when the Latin American economies did very well. Another caveat of the argument was that within the dual economy an augmented foreign investment led to greater inequality in incomes and attenuated foreign indebtedness. Dependency theorists dismissed the argument of the conventional economists that foreign trade and capital could be beneficial. However they did not satisfactorily deal with the problem of isolationism. GROSS FALLACIES The erstwhile socialist society pursued an isolationist economic policy with aims of self-sufficiency and independent development as demonstrated by the fact that they produced little less than 25 per cent of World GNP yet their share of world exports were merely 14 per cent. This also meant that they were out of the prevailing trend towards internationalisation of the production process and membership of financial institutions. The exclusiveness meant that the three important components of modern business organisation, increased efficiency, product quality and consumer choice did not be-come a part of their economic processes. In not dealing with these important issues the dependency theory ignored some of the very key issues of modern organisational structure and the role of scientific and technological innovations and in that sense is pre-modern. In course of testing the hypothesis of the dependency theory in the context of Latin America Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller took into account the relationship between the dependency economies and economic growth. They incorporated variables like degree of trade partner concentration, degree of concentration of commodities and flow of foreign capital and investment and found gross fallacies in the dependency theory. The majority of indicators pointed to the fact that the more dependent countries grew faster rather than slowly as contended by the dependency theorists. This was important for it falsified one of their core assumptions about dependency and economic growth. Furthermore, Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller also established the fact that though dependency produced income inequality yet there was a strong negative link between dependency and land inequality, disproving another major contention of the dependency theorists. (To be concluded) All Material Subject to Copyright Copyright 2000: The Statesman (India). All Rights Reserved. Quellen:ASIA INTELLIGENCE WIRE THE STATESMAN 27/12/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 27Dez2000 JAPAN: THE STATESMAN (INDIA) - COLUMN ONE - DEPENDENCY THEORY-I - History's Verdict Against It. By SUSHILA RAMASWAMY. IN the immediate aftermath of World War II, as a consequence of decolonisation, many new nations emerged and became full-fledged sovereign members of the world community. Their utmost consideration was economic development, eradicating poverty and raising the standards of living of their people. They understood that political independence alone was not enough unless they could achieve economic power and self-reliance. They carved out a distinct place in the world and styled themselves as the Third World with a definitive ideology that provided a radical critique of existing world order, one marked by sharp inequities and disparities. They questioned the rationale for their poverty and backwardness, which was in sharp contrast to the affluence of Europe, North America and Japan. Their emphasis was on the role of governments and controlling markets to bring about accelerated national economic growth. To find a solution to this problem many intellectuals began to question the proposition of classical economists like Adam Smith and Ricardo that growth in free world trading would abolish poverty and backwardness. There were two basic objections to this proposition. First that poverty was not inevitable and second, world market in itself was not adequate to tackle it. Governments in the developed countries played a central role by regularly intervening and regulating the market. NEOCOLONIALISM Raul Prebisch understood that the 19th century paradigm of free trade was inoperative and disadvantageous to these new raw materials exporting nations in the middle of 20th century. He stressed a solution that had both national and international ramifications. Internationally the centre ought to help the peripheries through foreign aid and technical assistance. It ought to give special treatment to raw materials exporting countries and aid the third world governments trying to reform domestic industry till a point when the nation consumed its own locally produced manufactured goods irrespective of the costs. Such an effort at import substitution would lessen dependence on imports and reduce the need to export simultaneously increasing domestic employment and income. This would result in an expanded domestic market accelerating the process of industrialisation. The dependency theory was Marxist in orientation but intellectually drew its sustenance from the non-Marxist analysis of Prebisch. It originated among the radical social scientists of Latin America. Using the Latin American experiences they developed their formulations. By giving a twist in the neo-Marxist direction to Prebisch's formulations dependency theory became a critique of the modernisation theory. Moderni-sation theory combining economic, psychological and sociological factors understood modernity to include value systems, individual motivation and capital accumulation. It emphasised considerably the role values, norms and belief-structures played in the transformation of a traditional society into a modern one. Dependency theorists rejected the modernisation theories both with regard to analysis and prediction. They associated under-development to the linkage under-developed countries had with the developed countries. Unlike Prebisch who suggested remedies both national and international, the depen-dency theorists analysed the problem of under-development within the framework of international structures and pro-cess. They followed the Leni-nist legacy of Marxism and connect the continued impoverishment and under-development of the periphery to the sustained unequal exchange with the developed West. While Lenin regarded imperialism as the last stage of capitalism the dependency theorists gloomily considered imperialism as the basis of perpetuating inequality and dependency. Unlike the development theorist for whom domestic factors were crucial to explaining poverty and backwardness the dependency theorists attributed the poverty of the poor countries to the affluence of and exploitation by the rich ones. They pointed to historical antecedents when the colonial powers deliberately thwarted the indigenous development of their colonies. For most of the newly independent countries political freedom remained meaningless since advanced countries through multinational corporations, foreign aid and technological and cultural dependence economically dominated them. This was established and perpetuated through a policy of collaboration bet-ween foreign and local capital with the help of the support base of a new class. GRAND NARRATIVE Andre Gunder Frank developed dependency theory into a grand one by emphasising the intrinsic link between under development and dependency with globalisation of capitalism. The dependency theorists contended that the distinction between un-development and underdevelopment was due to the mercantilist and capitalist expansion of the European powers. What followed was a unity of interests among the developed countries while the under-developed regions re-mained disunited. Since then the unequal relationship bet-ween the developed and underdeveloped regions continued with calamitous consequences for the latter. The dependency theorists located the problem of under-development in the very nature of contemporary capitalism and recommended the erstwhile Soviet model of industrialisation, in which the state rather than the consumer decided priorities as the only way out of the limitations of bourgeois reforms. A leap towards socialism would guarantee both a balanced growth and total national control over production and allocation of its resultant surplus. However they ignored one important historical fact that the socialist countries in the developing world suffered as much from the phenomenon of dependency as their own non-socialist counterparts. A good example was Cuba whose economy was paralysed and dependent on subsidy from the former Soviet Union to the tune of four billion dollars a year, half of Cuba's national income. Both Ethiopia and Vietnam in the early 80's faced virtual famines and had to be helped by the West to tide over the crisis. The Communist nations in the developing world were as much dependent on the developed socialist countries, as were the non-communist ones on advanced capitalist countries. The crux of the argument of the dependency theorists was that countries with a high deg-ree of dependency would have very low rates of economic growth. The growth rate in the satellites would be highest when their link with the centre is at the weakest. For instance Frank cited the examples of the two World Wars and the period of the Great Depression when the Latin American economies did very well. Another caveat of the argument was that within the dual economy an augmented foreign investment led to greater inequality in incomes and attenuated foreign indebtedness. Dependency theorists dismissed the argument of the conventional economists that foreign trade and capital could be beneficial. However they did not satisfactorily deal with the problem of isolationism. GROSS FALLACIES The erstwhile socialist society pursued an isolationist economic policy with aims of self-sufficiency and independent development as demonstrated by the fact that they produced little less than 25 per cent of World GNP yet their share of world exports were merely 14 per cent. This also meant that they were out of the prevailing trend towards internationalisation of the production process and membership of financial institutions. The exclusiveness meant that the three important components of modern business organisation, increased efficiency, product quality and consumer choice did not be-come a part of their economic processes. In not dealing with these important issues the dependency theory ignored some of the very key issues of modern organisational structure and the role of scientific and technological innovations and in that sense is pre-modern. In course of testing the hypothesis of the dependency theory in the context of Latin America Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller took into account the relationship between the dependency economies and economic growth. They incorporated variables like degree of trade partner concentration, degree of concentration of commodities and flow of foreign capital and investment and found gross fallacies in the dependency theory. The majority of indicators pointed to the fact that the more dependent countries grew faster rather than slowly as contended by the dependency theorists. This was important for it falsified one of their core assumptions about dependency and economic growth. Furthermore, Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller also established the fact that though dependency produced income inequality yet there was a strong negative link between dependency and land inequality, disproving another major contention of the dependency theorists. (To be concluded) All Material Subject to Copyright Copyright 2000: The Statesman (India). All Rights Reserved. Quellen:ASIA INTELLIGENCE WIRE THE STATESMAN 27/12/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 27Dez2000 JAPAN: THE STATESMAN (INDIA) - COLUMN ONE - DEPENDENCY THEORY-I - History's Verdict Against It. By SUSHILA RAMASWAMY. IN the immediate aftermath of World War II, as a consequence of decolonisation, many new nations emerged and became full-fledged sovereign members of the world community. Their utmost consideration was economic development, eradicating poverty and raising the standards of living of their people. They understood that political independence alone was not enough unless they could achieve economic power and self-reliance. They carved out a distinct place in the world and styled themselves as the Third World with a definitive ideology that provided a radical critique of existing world order, one marked by sharp inequities and disparities. They questioned the rationale for their poverty and backwardness, which was in sharp contrast to the affluence of Europe, North America and Japan. Their emphasis was on the role of governments and controlling markets to bring about accelerated national economic growth. To find a solution to this problem many intellectuals began to question the proposition of classical economists like Adam Smith and Ricardo that growth in free world trading would abolish poverty and backwardness. There were two basic objections to this proposition. First that poverty was not inevitable and second, world market in itself was not adequate to tackle it. Governments in the developed countries played a central role by regularly intervening and regulating the market. NEOCOLONIALISM Raul Prebisch understood that the 19th century paradigm of free trade was inoperative and disadvantageous to these new raw materials exporting nations in the middle of 20th century. He stressed a solution that had both national and international ramifications. Internationally the centre ought to help the peripheries through foreign aid and technical assistance. It ought to give special treatment to raw materials exporting countries and aid the third world governments trying to reform domestic industry till a point when the nation consumed its own locally produced manufactured goods irrespective of the costs. Such an effort at import substitution would lessen dependence on imports and reduce the need to export simultaneously increasing domestic employment and income. This would result in an expanded domestic market accelerating the process of industrialisation. The dependency theory was Marxist in orientation but intellectually drew its sustenance from the non-Marxist analysis of Prebisch. It originated among the radical social scientists of Latin America. Using the Latin American experiences they developed their formulations. By giving a twist in the neo-Marxist direction to Prebisch's formulations dependency theory became a critique of the modernisation theory. Moderni-sation theory combining economic, psychological and sociological factors understood modernity to include value systems, individual motivation and capital accumulation. It emphasised considerably the role values, norms and belief-structures played in the transformation of a traditional society into a modern one. Dependency theorists rejected the modernisation theories both with regard to analysis and prediction. They associated under-development to the linkage under-developed countries had with the developed countries. Unlike Prebisch who suggested remedies both national and international, the depen-dency theorists analysed the problem of under-development within the framework of international structures and pro-cess. They followed the Leni-nist legacy of Marxism and connect the continued impoverishment and under-development of the periphery to the sustained unequal exchange with the developed West. While Lenin regarded imperialism as the last stage of capitalism the dependency theorists gloomily considered imperialism as the basis of perpetuating inequality and dependency. Unlike the development theorist for whom domestic factors were crucial to explaining poverty and backwardness the dependency theorists attributed the poverty of the poor countries to the affluence of and exploitation by the rich ones. They pointed to historical antecedents when the colonial powers deliberately thwarted the indigenous development of their colonies. For most of the newly independent countries political freedom remained meaningless since advanced countries through multinational corporations, foreign aid and technological and cultural dependence economically dominated them. This was established and perpetuated through a policy of collaboration bet-ween foreign and local capital with the help of the support base of a new class. GRAND NARRATIVE Andre Gunder Frank developed dependency theory into a grand one by emphasising the intrinsic link between under development and dependency with globalisation of capitalism. The dependency theorists contended that the distinction between un-development and underdevelopment was due to the mercantilist and capitalist expansion of the European powers. What followed was a unity of interests among the developed countries while the under-developed regions re-mained disunited. Since then the unequal relationship bet-ween the developed and underdeveloped regions continued with calamitous consequences for the latter. The dependency theorists located the problem of under-development in the very nature of contemporary capitalism and recommended the erstwhile Soviet model of industrialisation, in which the state rather than the consumer decided priorities as the only way out of the limitations of bourgeois reforms. A leap towards socialism would guarantee both a balanced growth and total national control over production and allocation of its resultant surplus. However they ignored one important historical fact that the socialist countries in the developing world suffered as much from the phenomenon of dependency as their own non-socialist counterparts. A good example was Cuba whose economy was paralysed and dependent on subsidy from the former Soviet Union to the tune of four billion dollars a year, half of Cuba's national income. Both Ethiopia and Vietnam in the early 80's faced virtual famines and had to be helped by the West to tide over the crisis. The Communist nations in the developing world were as much dependent on the developed socialist countries, as were the non-communist ones on advanced capitalist countries. The crux of the argument of the dependency theorists was that countries with a high deg-ree of dependency would have very low rates of economic growth. The growth rate in the satellites would be highest when their link with the centre is at the weakest. For instance Frank cited the examples of the two World Wars and the period of the Great Depression when the Latin American economies did very well. Another caveat of the argument was that within the dual economy an augmented foreign investment led to greater inequality in incomes and attenuated foreign indebtedness. Dependency theorists dismissed the argument of the conventional economists that foreign trade and capital could be beneficial. However they did not satisfactorily deal with the problem of isolationism. GROSS FALLACIES The erstwhile socialist society pursued an isolationist economic policy with aims of self-sufficiency and independent development as demonstrated by the fact that they produced little less than 25 per cent of World GNP yet their share of world exports were merely 14 per cent. This also meant that they were out of the prevailing trend towards internationalisation of the production process and membership of financial institutions. The exclusiveness meant that the three important components of modern business organisation, increased efficiency, product quality and consumer choice did not be-come a part of their economic processes. In not dealing with these important issues the dependency theory ignored some of the very key issues of modern organisational structure and the role of scientific and technological innovations and in that sense is pre-modern. In course of testing the hypothesis of the dependency theory in the context of Latin America Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller took into account the relationship between the dependency economies and economic growth. They incorporated variables like degree of trade partner concentration, degree of concentration of commodities and flow of foreign capital and investment and found gross fallacies in the dependency theory. The majority of indicators pointed to the fact that the more dependent countries grew faster rather than slowly as contended by the dependency theorists. This was important for it falsified one of their core assumptions about dependency and economic growth. Furthermore, Kaufman, Cheronosky and Geller also established the fact that though dependency produced income inequality yet there was a strong negative link between dependency and land inequality, disproving another major contention of the dependency theorists. (To be concluded) All Material Subject to Copyright Copyright 2000: The Statesman (India). All Rights Reserved. Quellen:ASIA INTELLIGENCE WIRE THE STATESMAN 27/12/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 01Aug2000 USA: Development studies and comparative education - Context, content, comparison and contributors. By Little, Angela. ABSTRACT This article reviews Comparative Education over the past 20 years, explores the parallel literature of development studies, and identifies future directions and challenges for comparative education. Using Parkyn (1977) as a benchmark, an analysis of articles published between 1977 and 1998 suggests that only a small proportion appear to meet his criteria for comparative education. Parkyn's purpose for comparative education, to increase our understanding of the relationship between education and the development of human society, is shared by development studies. Educational writings within development studies have explored the meanings of development and underdevelopment and have raised important questions about the unit of analysis for comparative education. Several reasons are advanced to explain the separate development of these literatures. The contemporary challenge of globalisation presents fresh opportunities and challenges for both literatures. A shared commitment to understanding the role of education in the globalisation process and the reasoned response to it could form the heart of a shared effort in the future. Globalisation also highlights the need for more effective dialogue between comparative educators in different corners of the globe. Introduction The purpose of this article is three-fold: to provide a brief review of the journal over the past 20 years in terms of criteria it has set for itself; to identify concepts which have emerged from development studies over the past 20 years which can contribute to and enhance comparative education; and to conclude with suggestions about the future development of the field of comparative education. Review of the journal The benchmark for this review is Parkyn's (1977) contribution to the Special Number, entitled 'Comparative Education Research and Development Education' (Grant, 1977). Parkyn reflects on an issue which exercised a number of academics in the 1970s, the similarities and differences between comparative education and development education, and the potential contribution of the former to the latter. For Parkyn, the purpose of comparative education was: ... to increase our understanding of the relationship between education and the development of human society by taking into account factors that cannot adequately be observed and understood within the limits of any particular society, culture, or system, but that transcend particular societies and have to be studied by comparative methods applied to societies, cultures and systems ... (p. 89) Parkyn uses the term `development' to refer to all societies that are undergoing change. He does not confine the use of the term `development' to `developing' countries. The purpose of development education [1], by contrast, was: ... education aimed at the modernisation of ... technological activities in order to provide better for their material and cultural needs, and at the adaptation of their political machinery and other societal institutions in such a way as to make possible the most effective use of this modernisation in the satisfying of those needs. (p. 89) Despite the association in the minds of many of the term `development education' with `less developed' countries, Parkyn was at pains to point out that the fundamental distinction between comparative education and development education was not one of geography. The distinction was one of purpose. The purpose of comparative education was understanding and analysis, the purpose of development education was action and change. Comparative education could and should be undertaken in the countries of the North and the South. Wherever it is practised, development education should rest on a foundation of comparative education. Wherever in the world it was undertaken, the purpose of comparison was to explore the influence of system-level factors on the interaction of within-system variables. This definition of intellectual purpose in turn led to Parkyn's critique of comparative education in the 1970s. The inadequacy of many studies purporting to be comparative, and superficially appearing to be comparative, is, in the last analysis, to be found in the fact that those which concentrated on within system variables or cultural contexts have often lacked infor-mation on across-system variables, while those which have dealt with across-system variables have often failed to show their different interaction with within-system variables in different countries. (Parkyn, 1977, p. 90) So how has the field, as represented by studies published by Comparative Education, fared over the past two decades? Does the journal include a good representation of so-called `developing countries', in support of Parkyn's proposition that geography is not a defining characteristic of comparative education (context)? Does the journal include a good representation of articles addressing the fundamental question of comparative education, the relationship between education and the development of human society (content)? Does the journal demonstrate an understanding of the intellectual purpose of comparison (comparison)? The review classifies the titles of articles published by Comparative Education between 1977 and 1998 (Volumes 13-34). A total of 472 articles were classified by country context (Table I), content (Table II) and comparison (Table III) by the author and Dr Felicity Rawlings, working independently. While acknowledging that a title is only an indicator of an article's content, a classification based on a full reading of all 472 articles fell beyond the scope of the present review. Context Table I indicates the countries mentioned in the titles of articles. The authors of some 68% (320/472) of articles made explicit reference to one or more countries in the titles of their articles. Seventy-six countries were mentioned, just over one-third (34%) of the 224 countries listed in UNESCO's Statistical Yearbook 1998. A few countries have featured in the titles of a large number of articles, for example the UK (43), China (31), Japan (28), Germany (21), the USA (20), France (20) and Australia (16). Some 34 countries warrant mention in the title of only one article in 20 years. The number of countries that have at least one title published was compared with the total number of countries in the same region, as listed in UNESCO's Statistical Yearbook 1998. In Africa, some 17 countries appeared in the title of at least one article, compared with some 56 countries in the Africa region, or 30%. Asia, South America and Oceania achieved similar percentages. The countries of Europe achieved the highest representation of 56%, while those of North America were under-represented, at 16%. The apparent under-representation of titles from North America may be accounted for by the propensity of authors on North American education to contribute to our important sister journal, Comparative Education Review, based in North America. The similar levels of representation of countries in the other four continental blocs-Africa (30%), South America (36%), Asia (35%) and Oceania (30%)-is a significant achievement for a journal established in London and run from the UK, and publishing (currently) only in English. A comparison of the number of articles whose titles refer to one or more countries, by continent, presents a different picture. The total number of countries referred to in titles is 362. Just over half of this total refers to countries in Europe or North America (Europe 40.1%; North America 10.5%). A further 29.6% refer to Asia. Articles focusing on countries in Africa, South America and Oceania account for 11.3%, 1.9% and 6.6% respectively. If one excludes Australia and New Zealand from the Oceania bloc, the percentage falls to 1.6%. A classification by `developed' and `developing' country, using the 1998 UNESCO classification, presents an even sharper picture. UNESCO's Statistical Yearbook 1998 classifies 53 (24%) countries as `developed' and the remaining 171 (76%) as `developing'. Some 224 (62%) of our articles refer to `developed' countries, and 138 (38%) to `developing countries'. To the extent that a large number of developed and developing countries attract the attention of authors, Parkyn's proposition that geography is not the essential characteristic of comparative education appears to be borne out. At the same time, it is clear that over the past decades comparative educators have attended disproportionately on educational issues in the countries of Europe, North America and, to a degree, Asia. Content Table II presents the content of articles, as indicated by title, using the classification of journal aims published in 1978. The relationship between education and the development of human society, education and development for short, appears to lie behind 44 of the articles, or 13% of the articles classified by the 1978 scheme. Titles here include, for example, Blinco on 'Persistence and Education: a formula for Japan's economic success' (Blinco, 1993) and Morris on 'Asia's Four Little Tigers: a comparison of the role of education in their development' (Morris, 1996). These titles appear to address one aspect of Parkyn's definition of comparative education purpose, the relationship between education and the development of human society. Whether, simultaneously, they account for 'factors that cannot adequately be observed and understood within the limits of any particular society' (Parkyn, 1977, p. 89) requires a more careful reading of the text than has been possible in this brief review. A further 17.6% of articles address educational reform, including the internal problems of reform and the influence of societal development on the reform of education. The latter may be viewed as the inverse of the category noted above, the relationship between education and the development of human society. Titles here include Gu Mingyuan (1984) on 'The Development and Reform of Higher Education in China', La Belle & Ward (1990) on `Education Reform When Nations Undergo Radical Political and Social Transformation', and Mitter (1992) on `Educational Adjustments and Perspectives in a United Germany'. TABLE I. Around 10% of articles may be classified under the heading `significant aspects of comparative research'. This has been interpreted to include discussions of (i) comparative method; (ii) comparative theory; and/or (iii) comparisons drawn across a set of individual country papers. More than 100 articles could not easily be classified under the 1978 headings. Of these, 12 addressed cultural diversity and pluralism, 11 pedagogic and philosophical theory, 11 the education of minorities and 5 language policy. Comparison Table III presents the geographic scope of comparisons made. It distinguishes titles that refer to single countries, two or more countries, regional groups, the 'world', and those from which such reference is absent. This classification does not enable us to judge whether studies have identified the interaction between system-level and within system level factors, Parkyn's intellectual purpose of comparison. However, the very large number of studies, some 248 (58%), that focus on single countries, would suggest that Parkyn's criterion has not been met in more than half the cases. A smaller number, some 72 (15%), explicitly make comparisons across two, and less often, three, four or five countries. A further 11% indicate in their titles that the study draws on/makes reference to countries within a particular region (e.g. `developing' countries, `Europe', the Pacific, Africa). A very small number, some 3%, focus on globalising or internationalising trends, or on agencies (e.g. the World Bank) which have a global remit. Some 18% of titles omit reference to country focus. TABLE II. Among those which focus explicitly on a single country, some 145 (58%) focus on `developed' countries and 103 (42%) on developing. Of the titles that indicate comparison across one or more countries, the majority involves two-country comparisons. Of these, 42 (68%) are comparisons between two developed countries, 12 (19%) are comparisons be tween two developing countries, and the remaining eight (13%) make comparisons between developed and developing countries. The fairly sizeable percentage of articles that omit a reference to country (18%), are of many types. They include articles of the kind included in this Special Number, reviewing generally the state of the field and/or raising theoretical or methodological questions. Or they may focus on a particular country, but do not consider this focus to be sufficiently important to mention in the title. TABLE III. Among those that draw explicit comparisons across countries, the majority do so across developed countries. The majority of studies drawing comparisons across two countries, and all those across three and four, focus on developed countries. Those that draw comparisons across five countries include four developed countries and Singapore. The studies whose titles make a regional or global reference are difficult to classify further without detailed analysis of the content of the articles. It would appear then that only a small percentage of articles published by Comparative Education since 1977 have adopted an explicitly comparative approach. The majority of articles focus on single countries. Authors are contributing to a body of educational knowledge drawn from diverse educational settings. This is not to imply that the studies lack a comparative `dimension'. Many authors locate their studies in relation to the more general comparative education literature, and indeed are encouraged to do so by the journal. However, the primary focus of the study is a single country context. Context, Content and Comparison The above analysis indicates that the articles published in Comparative Education cover a very broad range of context, content and comparison. Parkyn's criteria are met by only a small proportion of articles. Geography is clearly not the defining characteristic of comparative education, although the representation of articles on countries in the `South' is not yet as high as it should be. The breadth of content areas covered goes well beyond Parkyn's prescription. And the `comparative' approach adopted by authors varies considerably. Breadth has the considerable advantage of bringing together readers with different and shared foci. Several of the Special Numbers of Comparative Education take a single country as their theme. Within this shared focus, authors address the specific issues of curriculum, teachers, management and employment. Other Special Numbers focus on a single topic, for example, post-compulsory education (Williams, 1994). Authors address this issue from a range of countries. Both of these approaches are valid, and encourage a two-stage approach to comparative education knowledge. In the first stage, country or topic specialists presented contextualised knowledge. In the second stage, comparative specialists synthesised and located context. The guest editor of the Special Number usually executes this second stage. In principle, if not always in practice, the guest editor can identify the interaction between system and within system factors, thus meeting Parkyn's definition of `comparative' purpose. Indeed, Parkyn's criterion of comparative purpose may be best handled through this two-stage approach. Well-contextualised knowledge about education is a necessary, and complex, first step in the process of comparison. Much comparison neglects context and renders itself superficial and meaningless. However, breadth of context, content and comparison has the disadvantage of dilution and a loss of focus for a field of study. In view of the number of articles that can be published each year, and the invitation for contributions from several disciplines, the potential for a loss of overall focus for the field of study increases greatly. Development Studies I turn now to the field of development studies and explore the impact it has had on comparative education. Development studies emerged in the 1950s and 1960s, in the wake of the processes of reconstruction and de-colonisation after World War II Key questions for development studies include: What does is mean to say that a society is developing or developed? What is the role of societal processes and institutions (such as education) in the process of development? What are the social and economic conditions that facilitate or impede the development of society? Thus, the fundamental questions of development studies with respect to education and those of comparative education, following Parkyn's definition, converge. Modernisation Theories of economic and social modernisation became central frameworks for the analysis of economic growth and societal development, and became influential also in determining national economic and social policy and policy implementation, as countries asserted their economic and political independence. Education was a central pillar of post-colonial social policy as countries sought to `modernise' and to replace expatriate highly skilled labour. Theories of development in developing countries, formulated largely by social scientists from the developed countries (although often working in developing countries), emerged alongside policies for development. From the outset economic goals formed the essential character of the `development project'. Education played an important part in development theory. The theory of `modernisation' presented an optimistic model for development of those societies that were not yet modern and industrialised. Modernisation theory attracted the attention of researchers from several social science disciplines. Economists focused attention on the application of technology to produce growth in economic production per unit of input. Sociologists focused on the process of social differentiation that characterise societies which use technology to promote economic growth. Demographers focused on patterns of settlement that accompany urbanisation, the impact of modernisation on population size, growth and density. Political scientists focused on nation-building, on the bases for power and how power is shared, how nation-states achieve legitimacy and the extent and depth of national identity. Research on the relationship between education and the modernisation of society was also pitched at the level of the individual. For example, McClelland (1961) focused on the values held by the majority of people in a society and the implications of these for economic and technological growth. The value attached to and the motivation for achievement, were central to McClelland's explanation of modernising societies. Where Max Weber (1930) had focused attention on the role of ideas and religion in setting the conditions for the rise of capitalism, McClelland focused on early socialisation and child rearing practices. Inkeles & Smith (1974) drew from both sets of ideas. They accepted the logic of modern values leading to modern behaviour, modern society, and economic development. In contrast to McClelland, however, they stressed the role of modern institutions such as the formal school and the factory in the formation of modern values and attitudes. Human Capital Education was also a central part of theories of development that focused on the economic imperatives and conditions for development. In one of the most influential writings on the role of education in development in the 20th century, Theodore W. Schultz explored the idea of education as a form of capital and introduced the notion of education as a form of human capital (Schultz, 1961). The propositions of `human capital' theory were that the skills and knowledge which people acquire are a form of capital. This capital was a product of deliberate investment and had grown in Western societies at a rate faster than `conventional' (non-human) capital. Its growth has been the most distinctive feature of the economic system of the mid-20th century. Human capital theory formed an important part of the development studies discourse about the relationship of education to the development of countries in the South from the mid-1960s. It emerged much later, from the late 1970s, as part of the discourse about education in the countries of the North. The role of education in modernisation was the subject of several well-known collections. For example, the collection on `Education and Economic Development', edited by Anderson & Bowman (1965), drew together historians, economists, sociologists, educators and geographers. It explored the role of education in economic development in Russia, India, America, Ghana, Chile, England and Japan. Another, edited in the same year by Coleman, entitled `Education and Political Development' (1965), focused on the political dimension of modernisation. Drawing on cases from the `developing areas' (former French Africa, Indonesia, Nigeria, Tunisia, Egypt and Brazil) and from countries where educational development has been `polity-directed' (Soviet Union, Japan, the Philippines), the book addresses the questions: What part can and does education play in the process of modernisation? What is the real (sic) relationship between political policy and the educational process? Dependency By the late 1960s and early 1970s the conceptual frameworks of both modernisation and human capital theory were coming to be challenged by a set of ideas which came to form the school of `dependency'. Marxist ideas on exploitation of the proletariat by the bourgeoisie, and Lenin's writings on imperialism, were developed by Andre Gunder Frank (e.g.1967) and Galtung (e.g.1971). Dependency theory addressed the extent to which poor countries were dependent on rich countries and the mechanisms through which economic dependency was maintained. The dependency perspective focused on under-development rather than development, viewing it as a necessary outcome of systematic exploitation and manipulation of peripheral economies by central economies (Frank, 1967; Cardoso, 1972; Dos Santos, 1973). Poor countries are conditioned by their economic relationships with rich economies to occupy a subordinate and dependent role that inhibits development by expropriating investible surplus. Indigenous elites, firmly wedded to the international capitalist system and rewarded handsomely by it, have no interest in giving up these rewards. Dependency theory accords overriding importance to the historical conditions that provide a context for development and to the international system of `global exploitation' managed by developed capitalist countries. Wallerstein (1974) presented an early formulation of a globalised economic system structured by world capitalism. The `dependency' perspective encouraged economists, political economists and sociologists to abandon the national economy, nation-state and national society as their central unit of analysis and to focus instead on the nature of relations between economies, states and societies. Dependency was conceived as a cultural phenomenon also. The structure of dependent economic relations was asserted to create a `cultural alienation' in which values, norms, technology, concepts and art forms were inspired externally rather than internally (Carnoy, 1974). Formal schooling in dependent economies played a key role in the furtherance of a cultural and economic dependency of peripheral upon central economies. Carnoy's thesis focused largely on schooling in the `Third World' Western formal education came to most countries as part of imperialist domination. It was consistent with the goals of imperialism: the economic and political control of the people in one country by the dominant class in the other. The imperial powers attempted, through schooling, to train the colonised for the roles that suited the coloniser (Carnoy, 1974, p. 3). The dependency school altered the discourse on education and development in a number of ways. It drew attention not only to the post-colonial or neo-colonial relations between countries which persisted long after so-called political independence, but it also focused attention on the analysis of the constraints on development, on stasis and decline in economy and society. It focused on the role of education for domination rather than for development. It provided answers to the question: How does education impede the process of development? It focused on the `negatives' of development. These included increasing disparities of income between social groups and countries, the continuing and increasing role of multi-national economic interests, the formation and co-option of transnational elite social groups, the divergence of values of different social groups, the creation and maintenance of underclass countries and groups. Education played a role in this through many social and cultural processes. These included the legitimation of elite social and economic status, through qualification systems, through curriculum and learning materials developed through international publishing projects, and through cross-national and inter-national professional networks (e.g. Mazrui, 1975; Altbach & Kelly, 1978; Watson, 1984; Lewin & Little, 1984; McClean, 1984). For those in the North, the dependency perspective was as challenging as it was uncomfortable. While it bore an intellectual relationship with emerging analyses of the role of education in the development of the US capitalist economy (e.g. Bowles & Gintis, 1976), it resonated most with those intellectual interests that lay in the colonised countries of the South or in the internally-colonised communities resident in countries in the North. As a set of ideas it bore closer links with the broader school of economic dependency than it did with the discourse of comparative education dominant at that time. It was substantially influenced by writers who appealed to notions of social equity in the perspectives they took on the processes of education and development. Thus, Carnoy acknowledges his particular intellectual debt to Raskin and Memmi, who wrote on colonialism and to Illich who promoted de-schooling in the developing countries and in the impoverished areas of developed countries. Comparative Education and Development Studies Compared Whereas the dependency perspective emerged as an intellectual response to modernisation theory and the questions it posed about the role of education in development (defined as modernisation), debates in comparative education in the late 1960s and 1970s concerned the methodology of comparative education. Questions included: What is the purpose of comparison? What types of question and evidence provide a legitimate basis for comparison? What is the appropriate focus for comparisons, as between systems and classrooms? What is the relative role of theory and practice in the generation of research questions? How is the comparative education method different from that of comparative sociology, comparative politics, comparative religion and philosophy, economic and social history, cross-cultural psychology? White much of this debate was conducted with considerable vigour and intellectual sophistication, it had the unintended effect of distracting attention away from the content questions that could usefully be addressed by using the methods) of comparative education. Method is valuable to the extent that its application provides new insights into a problem. What new insight could the comparative education method offer which comparative sociology, comparative social history, comparative politics or comparative social psychology could/did not? The methodological debates of the 1970s passed many people by and had little lasting impact, with a handful of exceptions. While a number of articles in Comparative Education adopted an explicitly comparative approach, few justified or explained their comparative approach in relation to those set out in the earlier debates. Interchange with comparative educators from many countries suggests that these debates have had little impact on the understanding or use of the so-called Comparative Education research method. A similar view was reached recently and independently by Rust et al., (1999) who reviewed almost 2000 articles appearing in Comparative Education (1964/95), Comparative Education Review (1957/ 95) and the International,journal of Educational Development (1981/95). The fundamental question of comparative education, according to Parkyn (1977), is the relationship between education and `development'. This question was fundamental also to those who wrote about modernisation and dependency. However, questions of method and country context distinguished the two literatures. Those who engaged most actively in the modernisation and dependency debates largely ignored the methodological debates in comparative education. Those who engaged most actively in the comparative methodological debates, drew their knowledge of educational context largely, although not exclusively, from the education systems of the North. Even those who designed the early IEA studies and drew inspiration from Noah & Eckstein's (1969) approach to comparative education addressed education mainly in the `developed countries'. In the first round of the International Association for the Evaluation of Educational Achievement (IEA) studies of 21 countries, only four, Chile, India, Iran and Thailand were, at that time, classified as `developing countries'. The driving question and problem behind the massive IEA research endeavour must be seen in the context of the Cold War and the race for supremacy in space. `Development' in this sense meant progress and world supremacy. It did not mean what it means for many of the `developing' countries-catch up, staying in the game, and basic survival. In short, the literatures addressing the fundamental question of the relationship between education and the development of human society have not been as integrated as they might have been. Two reasons for this less than optimal integration, suggested above, were the pre-occupation of comparative education, through much of the 1970s and 1980s, with debates about method, and the tendency for contributors to the field to focus their intellectual efforts on particular groups of countries. Three further reasons for the parallel rather than integrated development of the literatures of comparative education and development studies include differences in (i) the scope of analysis; (ii) the practice of development; and (iii) the emphasis on economic and cultural goals of society and development. Scope of Analysis The dependency approach suggested that national systems of education did not necessarily provide the most appropriate point of comparison for comparative studies. The scope of analysis needed to include contemporary and historical relations (of domination and dependency) between countries. This was especially so in the case of the former colonies. In principle then comparisons between countries needed to include their contemporary and historical relations of influence with other countries. Although the call for an historical approach in comparative education is familiar, it did not resonate with those who, at that time, were stressing comparisons of a contemporary nature. Nor did it resonate with those who sought comparisons across nations. The national system, economy and society remained for most comparative educationists the focus or unit of analysis. The notion of a national system of education sitting within a national economy and national society provided a clear focus for research that was within grasp. The implication of dependency theory-to include an analysis of education within international economic and political relations-was largely ignored by those whose knowledge of educational contexts drew largely from `developed' countries whose education systems, with some notable exceptions (e.g. see Phillips in this issue), had been largely immune from external influence. Practice The emergence of the education and development `business' contributed further to the parallel development of literature. Much of the early work on modernisation and its economic parallel, human capital theory, was used by development agencies and international banks to justify financial investments in education in developing countries. Schultz's (1961) work was especially influential in the 1960s and 1970s among those who allocated money to development programmes and those who promoted the growth of formal education world-wide. Significantly, many of these actors and agencies were external to the emerging states of the countries to be `assisted' or `aided'. The production of an educated labour force was perceived by both economists and development planners as a means to the end of the growth of the national economy, and hence, development. Not only did these ideas and writings bring the concepts and theories of economics to the centre stage of thinking about the relationship between education and development, but they did so in a way which smoothed (and sometimes ignored) the intellectual transition from analysis to advocacy, from description to prescription, from single cases to universal trends. Thus, many wrote of the relationship between education and development and ignored the multiplicity of possible relationships conditioned by variations in economic, cultural, social and political contexts and histories. These writings were oriented towards policy recommendations for the present and the future. In other words the writings were guided as much by the need to generate advocacies for education, as by the need to generate an understanding of why and how education was related to development in specific settings. The project of development, buttressed by financial resources and controlled by agencies external to the `developing' countries, encouraged a definition of development as economic growth and a discussion of the role of education in achieving that end. It encouraged a concern with immediate policies and practices and a tendency to seek policy recommendations of a `one size fits all' nature. Economic and Cultural Goals of/for Development The relative emphasis on economic and cultural definitions and explanations of development also distinguished the literatures. Human capital theory promoted the idea of education as a form of economic capital in the quest for development, defined as economic growth. It rendered subordinate supplementary and alternative ideas about the goals of learning and education-education as empowerment, education as citizenship, education as enculturation, education as liberation. The emphasis on economic development was accompanied by the notion that culture was separate from economy and impeded economic development. Culture was often invoked as an explanation of past failure rather than success, of present problems rather than achievements and of likely future difficulties rather than possibilities. Culture was treated frequently as a fixed and enduring endowment responsible for continuities and inhibiting change. This view was at odds with much that had been written on education and change in the `developed' countries of the North, where cultural analysis was more prominent. The Way Forward Aspects of the context of education and development in the so-called developed and developing countries have changed in ways which would have been unrecognisable to those who contributed to and read the 1977 Special Number of Comparative Education (Grant, 1977). These changes in turn present us with a fresh opportunity to reconstruct comparative education in ways that integrate rather than separate knowledge about education and development among the richest and the poorest social groups and countries. Already, there are signals that many of the old divisions apparent in the literatures could be breaking down. In developed countries the discourse on education, modernisation and economic competitiveness chimes uncannily with the discourse on human capital theory and modernisation in developing countries two or three decades ago. The `business' of development is arguably also influencing the discussion of education and development in the North as the work of universities becomes more commercialised and more driven by the needs of short-term policies and practices. The interest in `lessons from abroad' on the part of education policy-makers in developed countries increased markedly in the 1990s as the East Asian Tiger economies of the 1990s, themselves developing countries of the 1960s and 1970s, demonstrated enviable rates of economic growth [2]. There is a growing awareness that many of the jobs which educated young people in `developed' countries have done in the past will, in the future, be taken over by educated young people in `developing' countries. The marginalisation of large numbers of future generations-'social exclusion'-is a growing problem on the doorstep. Poverty is not confined to `developing' countries. Globalisation Underlying these signs is an economic and technological process we term `globalisation'. As Giddens notes: The term may not be a particularly attractive or elegant one. But absolutely no-one who wants to understand our prospects and possibilities at century's end can ignore it (Giddens, 1999a, p. 1) Writers in Comparative Education are already addressing it and many comparative education conferences have adopted it recently as a central theme (e.g. Comparative Education Web Page www.carfax.co.uk/ced-ad.htm, Watson, 1996; Cowen, 1996; Little, 2000a). The literature attracts 'sceptics' and 'radicals'. The sceptics dispute the whole thing ... Whatever its benefits, its trials and tribulations, the global economy isn't especially different from that which existed at previous periods. The world carries on much the same as it has done for many years ... (the radicals, by contrast argue) ... that not only is globalisation very real, but that its consequences can be felt everywhere. The global marketplace, they say, is much more developed than even two or three decades ago, and is indifferent to national borders. (Giddens, 1999, p. 1) For the radicals, the manifestations of so-called globalisation are economic, political or cultural. The economic include stateless financial markets, a massive expansion of world capital and finance flows, a rising proportion of global trade and investment in developing countries accounted for by transnational companies; the domination of international technology flows by transnational corporations (Wood, 1994; Stewart, 1996). The political manifestations of globalisation include a decline in state sovereignty (Ohmae, 1990); the reduced control of national governments over money supply and regulation of exchange rates; an increase in the power of global, sometimes stateless, organisations over national organ-isations; a definition of local issues in relation to the global as well as the local; and an increase in the ability of national and local issues to be played out on a world-stage. In the cultural arena the manifestations include a convergence of lifestyle and consumer aspirations among the better off, and the widespread distribution of images, information and values (Waters, 1995). The educational manifestations include the phenomenal growth in the flows of educational goods and services, in the revolution in modes of delivery of educational services, and in the definition of policy goals and curricula for education in developed and developing countries. The manifestations of globalisation are not the same as its underlying causes. For some (e.g. Wood, 1994) a major reduction of obstacles to international economic transactions constitutes the essential definition of globalisation. Hitherto, these obstacles have included transport and transaction costs, trade barriers, financial regulation, and speed of communication. Their reduction, a function of both economic policy and technological advance, has led to a major increase in the volume of international financial transactions. At the same time, the technological advances that have increased the speed of communication have facilitated connections not only between financial markets world-wide, but also between people worldwide. This is why the manifestations of globalisation are not simply economic; they are also political, social and cultural. They are personal as well as impersonal; they are `in here' as well as `out there' (Giddens 1999, p. 12). However, among those who acknowledge the phenomenon and consequences of globalisation, are the `optimists' and the `pessimists'. The optimists, like the development modernisers before them, concentrate on the positive consequences. The `pessimists', like the dependency theorists and the Marxists before them, concentrate on the negative. Development Studies For Grindle & Hilderbrand (1999) the heart of the mission of development studies has two aspects. Firstly, an understanding of the impact of globalisation, and secondly, a response to this understanding in ways that advance the positive and ameliorate the negative consequences of globalisation. Some of the current and projected `positives' and `negatives' of globalisation between and within developed and developing countries are presented in Table IV. The extension of these themes to education is inviting. The following questions, among others, emerge. How will different of forms of education, especially those supported by new information technologies, attain legitimacy and contribute to the improvement of living standards? How will education contribute to a heightened awareness of the need to provide economic, political and social opportunities for women and marginalised minorities? How will education contribute to democratic decision-making at national and local levels? How will education contribute to the functioning of international movements to improve institutions of governance, to counter corruption in public life and to adopt environmentally sound practices? How will differential access to education provision and quality contribute to the further marginalisation of young people? How will sanctions for countries that fail to adapt economic policies affect educational provision, especially for the poorest? How will different forms of education serve to legitimate and reproduce social and economic stratification? What will be the balance between local, national, international and global forces for educational decision-making? But to these should also be added a number of questions that emerge from conditions only weakly connected with globalisation, or from contexts where its particular effects are strongest. In many situations local and national influences will continue to be the most powerful in determining educational curriculum, control, resources, provision and outcomes. This requires sensitivity to and understanding of local and national contexts, and reinforces the earlier point about the need for comparative education to be grounded in an understanding of particular contexts. Such understanding will also generate issues common to regions and sub-regions. For example, at a recent Sub-Saharan Conference on Education for Ali, educators and researchers identified a number of priorities for research and action common to the Africa region and sub-region. These included the contribution of education to the alleviation of poverty, the impact of the HIV/AIDS pandemic on education and of education on its slow down, the provision of education in the context of emergency and post-conflict, and the contribution of education to the reduction of gender inequity and cultures of peace Johannesburg Declaration, 1999). Development studies captures the twin objectives of understanding and action, of analysis and advocacy, of policy analysis and policy prescription. It embraces the divide between `thinkers' and `do-ers'. It places on those who reflect, analyse, theorise about and study a responsibility to act, to advocate, and to prescribe. Simultaneously it places on those who act, do, advocate, and prescribe a responsibility to think about and question their own actions and the advice they give to others, especially in situations where power relations are unequal, within a broad scheme of global, national and local influence. Understanding and action are both important and valuable. Each requires overlapping but separate skills. While each benefits from the other, neither can be reduced to the other (Little, 2000b). The understanding of the role of education in the globalisation process within the framework presented in Table IV and the reasoned response to it could form the heart of the both the development studies and comparative education effort over the next few decades in both the developed and the developing countries. TABLE IV The Challenges Marginalisation, communication and access to information are key themes in the globalisation discourse. As editors of Comparative Education we frequently discuss how to encourage contributors and contributions from a larger number and wider range of 'developing countries'. If we are to encourage a better understanding of the relationship between education and 'development', both in terms of national and international development, then we need to find more effective means of promoting dialogue between comparative educators in different corners of the globe. At the beginning of this article I provided a review of context, content and type of comparison employed in Comparative Education articles published between 1977 and 1998. A review of the authors' 'address for correspondence' provides an indication of the communication and information challenge ahead. It also provides the final theme of the subtitle of this article. While 'address for correspondence' is a perfect proxy for neither nationality nor country of residence or domicile, it does indicate authors' current location in non-virtual space. Some 609 authors contributed to 472 published articles. While the total number of countries mentioned explicitly in the title of articles was 76, the number of countries in which contributors were based was 50. Some 85% of the contributors were based in developed countries. Only 15% were based in developing countries. In other words, the country base of authors is more concentrated than the countries they study, and the under-representation of authors based in developing countries is even more marked than the under-representation of articles based on them. Those of us who wish to inhabit a truly global and comparative field of study which can, in turn, make its own modest contribution to the cause of human progress, must create virtual and non-virtual space to encourage the participation of and exchange between educators from a much greater diversity of educational culture than hitherto. We must be sensitive to the diversity of educational and other contexts world-wide, achieve consensus on the fundamental questions of comparative education, and embrace in our comparisons local, national, regional, international and global spheres of influence. This is our collective challenge. Acknowledgements I am grateful for assistance and comments on an earlier draft of this paper from Jane Evans, Felicity Rawlings, Chris Williams and members of the Editorial Board of Comparative Education. NOTES [1] It should be noted that Parkyn's use of the term 'development education' reflected common usage in the USA at that time. In England the term 'development education' usually referred to the curricula of teaching courses, largely at school level, which aimed to increase school-children's knowledge and understanding of the problems of poverty in the countries of the South. In the 1970s the equivalent of Parkyn's usage in England might have been the practice (as distinct from the study) of education in developing countries. [2] The waning of interest in the wake of the end of the century crisis in those same economies illustrated the perils of cherry-picking and the importance of serious comparative analysis. REFERENCES ALTBACH, P.G. & KELLY, C.P. (Eds) (1978) Education and Colonialism (London, Longman). ANDERSON, C.A. & BOWMAN, M.J. (Eds) (1965) Education and Economic Development (Chicago, Aldine Publishing Company). BLINCO, P.M.A. (1993) Persistance and education: a formula for Japan's economic success, Comparative Education, 29(2), pp. 171-183. BOWLEA, S. & GINTIS, H. (1976) Schooling in Capitalist America (New York, Basic Books). CARDOSO, F. (1972) Dependency and development in Latin America, New Left Review, 74. CARNOY, M. (1974) Education as Cultural Imperialism (London, Longman). COLEMAN, J.S. (Ed.) (1965) Education and Political Development (Princeton, New Jersey, Princeton University Press). COWEN, R. (Ed.) (1996) Comparative education and post-modernity, Comparative Education, Special Number (18), 32(2). DOS SANTOS, T. (1973) The crisis of development theory and the problem of dependence in Latin America, in: H.BERNSTEIN Underdevelopment and Development: the Third World today, pp. 57-80 (Harmondsworth, Penguin). FRANK, A.G. (1967) Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America (New York, New York Monthly Review Press). GALTUNG, J. (1971) A structural theory of imperialism,,Journal of Peace Research, 8(2), pp. 81-117. GIDDENS, A. (1999) Runaway World (Cambridge, Polity). GRANT, N. (Ed.) (1977) Comparative education-its present state and future prospects, Comparative Education, Special Number, 13(2). GRINDLE, M.S. SC HILDERBRAND, M.E. (1999) The Development Studies Sector in the United Kingdom: challenges for the new millennium, Report to the Department for International Development, UK. INKELES,, A. & SMITH, D. (1974) Becoming Modern (London, Heinemann). JOHANNESBURG DECLARATION OF EDUCATION FOR ALL ( 1999) Draft document tabled for discussion at the Sub-Saharan Africa Conference on Education for All, 6-10 December, (Johannesburg, EFA Regional Technical Advisory Group). LA BELLE, T.J. & WARD, C.R. (1990) Education reform when nations undergo radical political and social transformation, Comparative Education, 26(1), pp. 95-106. LEWIN, K.M. & LITTLE, A.W. (1984) Examination reform and educational change in Sri Lanka, 1972-1982: modernisation or dependent underdevelopment, in: K.WATSON Dependence and Interdependence in Education: international perspectives, pp. 47-94 (Beckenham, Croom Helm). LITLE, A.W. (Ed.) (2000a) Globalisation, qualifications and livelihoods, Assessment in Education, Special Issue (forthcoming, 7(3)). LITTLE, A.W. (2000b) Post Jomtien models of educational development: anlaysis vs advocacy, in: L-E. MALMBERG, S-E. HANSEN & K. HEINO (Eds) Basic Education for All: a global concern far quality (Vasa, Abo Akademi University). MAZRUI, A. (1975) The African university as a multi-national corporation: problems of penetration and dependency, Harvard Educational Review, 45, pp.199-210 McCLEAN, M. (1984) Educational dependency: two lines of enquiry, in: K.WATSON Dependence and Interdependence in Education: international perspectives, pp. 21-29 (Beckenham, Croom Helm). MCCLELLAND, D. (1961) The Achieving Society (New York, The Free Press). MINGYUAN, G. (1984) The development and reform of higher education in China, Comparative Education, 20(1), pp. 141-148. MITTER,, W. (1992) Educational adjustments and perspectives in a united Germany, Comparative Education, 28(1), pp. 45-52. MORRIS, P. (1996) Asia's Four Little Tigers: a comparison of the role of education in their development, Comparative Education, 32(1), pp.95-109. NOAH, H. & ECKSTEIN, M. (1969) Toward a Science of Comparative Education (New York, Macmillan). OHMAE,(1990) The Borderless World power and strategy in the global marketplace (London, Harper Collins). PARKYN, G.W. (1977) Comparative education research and development education, Comparative Education, 13(2), PP-87-94. RUST, V., SOUMARE, A., PESCADOR, O. & SHIBUYA, M. (1999) Research strategies in comparative education, Comparative Education Review, 43(1), pp. 86-109. SCHULTZ, T.W. (1961) Investment in human capital, American Economic Review, 51, pp. 1-17. STEWART, F. (1995) Globalisation and education. Keynote address, UKFIET Conference on Globalisation and Learning, New College, Oxford. STEWART, F. (1996) Globalisation and education, International Journal of Educational Development, 16(4), pp. 327334. UNESCO (1998) Statistical Yearbook 1998 (Paris, UNESCO). WALLERSTEIN,,STEIN, I. (1974) The Modern tm World System: capitalist agriculture and the origins of the European world economy in the sixteenth century (London, Academic Press). WATERS, M. (1995) Globalisation (London, Routledge). WATSON, K. (1984) Dependence and Indpendencein Education: international perspectives (Beckenham, Croon Helm). WATSON, K. (Ed.) (1996) Globalisation and Learning, Special Issue of International J - ournal of Educational Development, 16(4). WEBER, M. (1930) The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (London, Allen & Unwin). WILLIAMS, V. (Ed.) (1994) Edmund King's contribution to post-compulsory education: an international review and appreciation, Comparative Education, Special Number (16), 30(t). WOOD, A. (1994) North-South Trade, Employability and Inequality: changing fortunes in a skill-driven world (Oxford, Clarendon Paperbacks). Correspondence to: Angela Little, Educational and International Development, Institute of Education, University of London, 20 Bedford Way, London WC1H OAL, UK. E-mail: a.little@ioe.ac.uk ANGELA W. LITTLE is Professor of Education (with special reference to Developing Countries), and Head of the International and Educational Development Group, at the Institute of Education, University of London. She was formerly a Fellow of the Institute of Development Studies at the University of Sussex, England. She is currently directing research programmes on Globalisation, Qualifications and Livelihoods in Sri Lanka and Zimbabwe; and on Multi-grade Teaching in Peru, Sri Lanka and Vietnam. Correspondence: International and Educational Development, Institution of Education, University of London, 20 Bedford Way, London WC1H OAL, UK. Email: a.little@ioe.ac.uk This article reviews Comparative Education over the past 20 years, explores the parallel literature of development studies, and identifies future directions and challenges for comparative education. Using Parkyn (1977) as a benchmark, an analysis of articles published between 1977 and 1998 suggests that only a small proportion appear to meet his criteria for comparative education. Copyright Carfax Publishing Company Aug 2000 Quellen:UMI COMPARATIVE EDUCATION 08/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 10Mai2000 AUSTRALIA: Getting to know our place. By Paul Monk. Australia's relationship with its neighbours turns not only on economic ties but also on the idea of the difference of Asia, writes Paul Monk ENGAGEMENT: Australia Faces the Asia-Pacific Paul Keating Macmillan, $40 hb, 310pp ASIAN VALUES, WESTERN DREAMS: Understanding the New Asia Greg Sheridan Allen & Unwin $29.95 pb, 326pp `THE POST-COLD WAR ERA never happened," Paul Bracken wrote last year. "It was a western conceit ... The world now is going through ... what is not a post-Cold War era but a post-Vasco da Gama one ... China, India and Persia were once the great civilisations of the world ... What is now taking place is a reassertion of these societies, with a capitalist economy and the modern technology of atomic bombs and missiles. Seen this way, the end of the Vasco da Gama era - which began in the late 16th century - has the most profound implications for the world, far more than the end of a communist state established in 1917." Bracken's Fire in the East: The Rise of Asian Military Power and the Second Nuclear Age (HarperCollins) is one of a number of dramatic and provocative books of the 1990s that heralded the eclipse of western global dominance and the coming of what Andre Gunder Frank called the "Asian age". Perhaps the best known of these books is Samuel Huntington's The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order (Simon & Schuster, 1996). Fear that something such as this could be coming, confusion about what it all means and lack of clarity about what "western" means in the global scheme of things generated the great debate of the 90s: is there a new, post-western form of capitalism and is it based on "Asian values" that are radically different from and even inimical to "western values"? If so, how do we rise to the challenge of Asia, now that it has risen to our challenge? No "western" country is more clearly challenged by these questions than Australia. We are the most substantial, and now the only remaining, da Gama-era western enclave in Asia. We may tell ourselves that we do not have to choose between our history and our geography, but our geography has been encroaching on our history for many years, like rising seas in an epoch of global warming, and whatever betide, our future will differ from our past because of our geography. It is vital, therefore, that we confront the fear and confusion about Asia and "Asian values" that have marred public debate and policy in this country for many years; and that we overcome the lack of clarity about "western values" that seriously impedes our efforts to come to terms with "Asian values". If we can do these things, then even in a worst-case scenario, we shall be able to conduct ourselves with honour and courage. If we do not, then, even in the best state of affairs, we shall continue to quarrel with one another, bemuse or irritate our neighbours and forfeit the considerable opportunities our circumstances present to us. Has Asia pioneered a new form of capitalism that is set to out-compete the West? The Asian economic crisis of the late 90s and the continuing stagnation of Japan might reasonably be seen as casting serious doubt on such a claim. Across Asia, in the wake of the crisis, the most thoughtful individuals declared that it had showed just how far Asia still has to go in understanding contemporary capital markets and establishing public accountability standards that will put an end to pseudo-capitalism, crony capitalism and corruption. While International Monetary Fund and World Bank handling of the crisis has been widely criticised, it has been criticised primarily from the point of view that new, better and more sensitive instruments for equilibrating the uncertainties of the global economy need to be developed. There have, of course, been some indications of defensiveness in parts of Asia, but these have been expressions or symptoms of vulnerability, not the war cries of a rampant new way of doing business. And, encouragingly, rapid growth has resumed in many parts of Asia, most spectacularly in South Korea, well ahead of what was expected in the tumultuous months of 1998. Above all, however, it is the US and to some extent Europe that are setting the trend in innovation and economic integration, with Asia still looking to get fully into the game. In brief, the evidence of the past few years would appear to suggest it is not a new capitalism we are seeing, but a large number of new capitalists and the rapid mutation of the global capitalist economy. The danger is not of Asia, in any corporate sense, overrunning the West, but of the global set of rules that make the high-stakes game of capitalism possible at all breaking down. Ensuring this does not happen is the active concern of Asian and western thinkers and leaders. How, then, do they converse: in the language of "western values" or the language of "Asian values"? Those who still see the West as imperialist and as dominating Asia, or attempting to do so, might respond by saying that the process verges on a dialogue of the deaf, with the West (principally Washington) shouting in "western values" at Asia and the latter making blurred or sullen replies in Asian values. But isn't this a bit like suggesting that such international dialogue is conducted by one side shouting in English and the other answering in Mandarin or Hindi or Japanese? In reality, what has been happening ever since da Gama is that a long process of interpretation and translation has been going on, in which the substance of things at stake - means of exchange, methods of technological innovation, uses of force and wonders of cuisine - has gradually overcome barriers of natural language and immemorial custom. That's why Bracken's Asian states have converged on capitalist methods of running their economies. That's why his Asian states have learned how to develop and use modern weaponry and experimental science. That's why, at the beginning of the Chinese Republic, Sun Yat-sen announced the abolition of the old lunar calendar and its replacement with the western solar calendar - bowing not to colonial power but to superior accuracy and utility. Bracken and Huntington notwithstanding, the great secular trend has not been simply western colonialism followed by Asian revival, but the global breakthrough into rationalism and empiricism. That breakthrough profoundly altered the West and is now altering the human and natural world as a whole, as human beings everywhere discover the freedom and productivity these methods make available. Is this to imply that old Hindu or Confucian ways of seeing the world are erroneous and epistemologically inferior to western critical rationalism and empiricism? Yes, it is; just as it is to say that Catholic medieval scholasticism or proto-scientific alchemy are inferior to such methods. That was the contention of Francis Bacon some 400 years ago. And it is the contention of all those who now seek and strive for a global human civilisation. It is not anti-Asian, but it does radically challenge insular and inward-looking traditions, for the same reason that it tells us the earth is not flat and the sun does not revolve around our planet and there are countless worlds in the universe. This is not a matter of "western values" versus "Asian values", but of universal cognitive humanism versus archaism and authoritarianism, wherever and in whatever form they present themselves. It is against this background that we should, I suggest, think through what is at stake for Australia in the debate over the rise of Asia, "Asian values" and the future of this country, given its geography. If we do not, if we try to think it through in terms of post-colonial guilt or postmodern relativism, of the calculus of raw power or the conceit of irreducible cultural uniqueness, we shall flounder. No physical science can be built on such foundations. No economic science can be developed from such premises. No principles of moral, ethical or political conduct, no norms as regards human rights, can coherently be developed on such a basis, but only on the testable basis that as humans we have more in common, including an investigable material reality, than our cultures tell us set us apart. It is this assumption that makes possible translation between natural languages, scientific method and transmission of knowledge. It also enables us to create international institutions and promulgate intelligible principles of human rights. It is with such an assumption in mind, I suggest, that one should read Paul Keating's Engagement: Australia Faces the Asia-Pacific. Keating, as prime minister, declared before the House of Representatives in Canberra, on his return from the APEC summit in Bogor at the end of 1994: With Bogor ... Australians can say for the first time that the region around us is truly `our region'. We know its shape, we have an agreed institutional structure, we share with its other members a common agenda for change ... Just as the Bretton Woods agreements after World War II established structures in the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank, which enabled the world to grow and prosper, so in APEC we have established a model which will serve the interests of the post-Cold War world. The only way to make sense of these propositions is by seeing them as grounded in the sort of universalist perspective I have just outlined. Agreed institutional structures and common agendas for change are necessarily grounded in principles that transcend particular or insular values and interests. Just to the extent that the reasons for creating such agreement and such a common agenda are clear and compelling, the principles on which they are based will have a logical and moral force that will transcend and, in the end, reshape the disparate values and interests out of which the initial agreement and agenda were hammered. The possibility of such agreements and common agendas, not the dominance of western power over "Asian values", is what civilisation and the civilising process are about. "Progress" is about already established civilisations being open to the renewal and extension of prior agreements and agendas, on the basis of deepened awareness of what is universally true and/or good. And this holds for folk customs, religious beliefs, political principles and moral prejudices as much as it does for claims about nature or the negotiation of economic interests. This is the way forward and Keating was surely correct to hail Bogor as the right sort of step in the right sort of direction. What is impressive and even inspiring about Keating's book is that he has come close to articulating a specifically Australian set of interests and concerns against the background of an at least implicit universalist humanism. There is in his reflections throughout the book a vigour, an urgency and a freshness of vision that would, in themselves, be something of an education for many an inward-looking and philistine Australian and which, if read abroad, not least in Asia, would reflect well on Australia. Those who considered Keating, the treasurer and prime minister, arrogant and out of touch with "Australian values" would do well to read this book. They might find themselves becoming engaged by his energy, his commitment to Australia's prospects and his worldly optimism. Keating writes: Here we sit, 19 million of us, drawn from more than 120 countries, on the edge of Asia, and with all the resources of a continent to draw on. What an astonishing bequest it is. We cannot turn away and we cannot turn back. It is the most exhilarating and promising prospect. And this does not come across as empty rhetoric. It comes across, in the context of his sustained reflections, as something passionately felt and actively lived for. It truly is a memoir of hope that Keating has written and the allusion to the memoirs of Charles de Gaulle is deliberate. The difference is chiefly this: that de Gaulle was 20 years older when he wrote Memoires d'espoir: Le Renouveau (1970) than Keating is now and had more completely retired. De Gaulle's reflections were more fully considered, his prose more polished and his immersion in his native culture more secure than one could say of Keating. Engagement: Australia Faces the Asia-Pacific has something of the character of Keating's prime ministership about it: something composed in haste and improvised with elan and force, but left incomplete and lacking, therefore, in the style and durability that make a political life or a book a classic. Yet even in offering us these hurried reflections he has gone further than has any Australian prime minister before him. Just think how profound an impression might be made on the minds of Australians by a really great book, written with the scope and magnanimity the subject deserves, rather than with the impatience and self-consciousness that are so characteristic of our contemporary way of being. It is, I think, the better efforts by Asian writers to articulate social experiences of upheaval and transformation with just such scope and magnanimity that chiefly moves Greg Sheridan to the reflections he has offered in Asian Values, Western Dreams: Understanding the New Asia. Sheridan celebrates the novels of Asian writers of his generation, such as Vikram Seth (India), K.S. Maniam (Malaysia), Yi Munyol (South Korea) and Francisco Sionil Jose (The Philippines), that attempt to dramatise their people's struggle with western-prompted modernisation. He is stirred by the spectacle of Asian idealists and democratic activists striving for reform, as well as by the spectacle of Asian technocrats and strongmen driving their nations into modernisation of one sort or an-other. He urges empathy with the difficulties and as-pirations of Asians and a greater effort to try to see the world (and ourselves) through their eyes. Like Keating, Sheridan passionately believes that Australia's best hopes and necessary destiny lie in creating a new history grounded in both our priceless western heritage and the challenges of our geography on the edge of Asia. His energy and his search for a workable renovation of Australia are also evident. All this is admirable. Yet his book is less intellectually satisfying or likely to make an enduring impression than Keating's. It is a book of anecdotes and impressions, but one searches in vain for a systematic argument that would make sense of its title. It is very readable and perhaps many people will read it and pick up vignettes from it that will add to their capacity to converse about Asia, but it is both confused and confusing as regards the underlying issues, including the nature of "Asian values". Sheridan declares that there are Asian values and that the West generally, and Australia in particular, needs to take greater cognisance of them. He never clearly distinguishes, however, between there being states of affairs called Asian cultures, or diverse ethical traditions, or folk customs, or political regimes, or even literary traditions and vernacular languages, so that "Asian values" comes to mean everything and nothing. At the end of nearly 300 pages of reflections and anecdotes, he confesses that he is "unable to state precisely, in a neat formula, what Asian values are", but that "the idea that there is no such thing as Asian values must mean that Jose Rizal, Kim Dae-jung and the rest are not Asians". But it is not anything specifically Asian for which either of those two individuals is famous. It is for standing up within an oppressive context (Spanish colonialism and South Korean military dictatorship, respectively) and insisting that as a matter of reason and principle the oppressors should "let my people go". Filipinos do not revere Rizal because he was "Asian", nor even because he was Filipino, but because he stood for their freedom. And we can all admire him for exactly this reason, just as we admire Martin Luther King jr, or Nelson Mandela, Mohandas Gandhi or Andrei Sakharov not because they were black, or brown, African, Indian or Russian, but because they stood for principles that we can all recognise and applaud. Sheridan more or less knows this, but he fails to think through its implications with any consistency. "There are, of course, universal values of good and evil," he remarks very early in his book, "but different societies and different traditions mediate them in vastly different ways." There are two problems here that he does not address. First, he never attempts to explain how he feels able to state flatly that there are "of course" universal values of good and evil. Second, he doesn't explain what precisely he means by "mediated in vastly different ways". Suppose, for example, I were to state that there is of course only one physical reality, but it is mediated by different cultures and traditions in vastly different ways. Would it not be reasonable to ask: "Sure, but then how is any objective knowledge or scientific research actually possible?" Or suppose I was to state that there are of course linguistic universals, but languages mediate them in vastly different ways. Would it not be reasonable to respond: "Perhaps, but then how do we know that there are such universals and how is good translation possible?" The intellectual problem with Sheridan's approach to Asian values is that he never seems to have asked himself these elementary analytical questions. The consequence is that he is unable to offer a coherent account of how values come about, are sustained and may be critically evaluated. Very broadly, he suggests more than once, Asians value authority, whereas the West has become rather antinomian. Well, perhaps, but where do we go from there? He seems to have no real idea. Quite a few of his Asian interlocutors seem to be far less confused about the matter and it is a wonder that this did not set him thinking more systematically. Amien Rais, the prominent Indonesian Muslim leader, told him with refreshing candour: "Asian values are a kind of protection for Asian leaders, to justify behaviour which is not democratic. To me, democratic values are universal. Asian values were really a ploy to defend undemocratic actions ... No political system is perfect, but democracy is best." It is characteristic of Sheridan, I think, to quote Rais on this matter uncritically, but to pour scorn on Christopher Patten for saying exactly the same thing in his East and West: China, Power and the Future of Asia (Macmillan, 1998). He ridicules Patten for an "immensely unsophisticated dismissal of Asian values", but when Asian leaders declare in favour of universal values, he seems to allow that they are being thoughtful and magnanimous. Conversely, he asserts that Singapore is attractive to "mainland Chinese" because it is authoritarian and does not suffer from "what Beijing used to see as a sort of moral anarchy in Hong Kong and Taiwan". Pardon me? "Beijing" has to mean the Chinese Communist Party. Moral anarchy? One can only guffaw at the idea that the Chinese Communist Party is in any position to decry the moral conduct of government or society in Hong Kong or Taiwan. "Often you get the feeling," writes Sheridan, "that western opinion leaders who comment on Asian values just don't like having Asians talk back to them." Perhaps, but what is rather more obvious is that Asian leaders who talk of Asian values have exhibited to a marked degree an unwillingness to have their own citizens talk back to them, and that is the fundamental point at issue in the Asian values debate. It was none other than Hu Yaobang, while secretary-general of the Chinese Communist Party's central committee, who declared to European interlocutors in 1986 that China needed to get rid of the "outdated" ideas of Marx, embrace the achievements of all humanity and adopt the ideas of political freedom advocated by Montesquieu. That is to say, principles of government that would moderate and divide the exercise of state power and explicitly place checks on possible despotic use of it. Why? Not because Hu felt intimidated by the West, but because he had thought his way through China's experience, as Rais had Indonesia's, and arrived at something he saw as true. Australia's role in Asia and in the world at large is - more than ever, and in our own interests - to stand up for and to further that sort of thinking. Our engagement with Asia can and should be grounded in thinking at that level of clarity. It isn't a matter of imperialism, but a matter of reality and a measure of our common humanity. Keating's vision hints at this. Sheridan's reflections blur it, though with the best of intentions. If Bracken's century unfolds, we shall badly need to keep a grip on that reality, using it to steer ourselves through stormy seas. If, instead, Bogor was the harbinger of a more benign future than Bracken fears, it will be because universalist principles enable us to build agreed institutions and fruitful common agendas with our diverse, energetic and creative Asian neighbours. *. (c) Nationwide News Proprietary Ltd, 2000. Quellen:AUSTRALIAN (THE) 10/05/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 01Apr2000 AFRICA: Globalization, regionalism and democracy - An interview with Samir Amin. By Anonymous. Samir Amin heads the Third World Forum in Dakar, Senegal, where he is leading an effort to strengthen regional ties among African nations. He is the author of many books, including: Capitalism in the Age of Globalization, Delinking: Toward a Polycentric World and Unequal Development. Multinational Monitor: What do you mean when you say that the world capitalist system is facing stagnation? Samir Amin: After World War II, we had very high rates of growth for three decades in the three parts of the world: the capitalist world (the West), the socialist world (the East), and most parts of the Third World (the South). Three decades of high growth and investment, which had never been achieved in the history of capitalism before. This is precisely because the markets were regulated - that is, because there was a balance of forces between capital on the one hand, and the working or popular classes on the other hand. This balance was less in favor of capital than it had been for a long time before, and was the result of a double victory - the victory of democracy over fascism and the victory of the people of Asia and Africa over colonialism. These two popular victories created the conditions which compelled capital to adjust to the social demands of working people. The adjustment of capital to those demands is the meaning of the market being regulated. Capital was unable to unilaterally impose the logic of profit maximization. That was the basis of high growth and accelerated rates of accumulation and development. Gradually, the balance of forces has been eroded to the benefit of capital for a variety of reasons. If we look at the West in the capital centers, the pattern is that welfare states and democracy have been gradually eroded by the pressures of globalization - the opening of national economies to the pressures of the global system. In the East, it is because of the internal limits of so-called socialism and the lack of democracy. In the South - especially in Asia and Africa there was a period of strong national unity which started to be eroded by internal social conflicts. This erosion of the regulation of the market which dominated after World War II led to a change in the balance of forces to the benefit of capital. We can say that Reagan and Thatcher were the announcement of that. But it was not just under Reagan and Thatcher. It was also due to the loss of legitimacy of most national radical popular regimes of the South, as well as the stagnation of the Soviet system. That led to a comeback of the utopian capitalist dream of ruling the world as a market and reducing whole societies to just market-based relations. Which means the unilateral domination of capital. MM: And removing regulations on capital undermined growth? Arvin: According to the so-called neoliberal view, "deregulation" of the market - which meant oppressing other social interests - should have led to higher growth. Instead, it led to the opposite. Since the early 1970s, it led to a slowing of the rates of growth, to about half of what they had been in previous decades. This happened not only in the West, but also in the East after high growth rates during the Soviet period of industrialization. It also happened in the South. In the 1960s, the rates of growth in Africa were roughly twice as high as they have been in the 1980s and 1990s during the current period of structural adjustment. Simultaneously, rates of investment and the expansion of the productive system went down. That led to a new kind of crisis characterized by a surplus of capital which does not find an outlet in the expansion of the productive system in the West, East and South. In order to avoid this problem, the owners of capital are designing rules in order to open alternative financial outlets for capital. This is not leading to higher growth but to relative stagnation of growth. There is no absolute stagnation, but rates of growth in OECD countries are half of what they had been in the 1950s and 1960s. There is deepening inequality. You have growing inequality everywhere in the world, within each nation state and at the global level between nations. It is more and more politically and socially unbearable and unacceptable to people. The reason for the deep crisis of capital is precisely the utopian effort to realize the unilateral rule of capital. The system cannot function according to the unilateral rule of capital. MM: There has been a renewal of growth in the last couple of years in the United States at much higher rates. Do you think that the new communications technologies might revitalize the global economy? Amin: No. We should separate the eventual effect of the technological revolution and particularly communications on the one hand, and the specif is effects of that revolution and other technologies on the relative achievements of the various partners - the U.S. vis-a-vs Europe, for instance. With respect to the effects of the technological revolution, every period of deep structural crisis of capitalism has also been a period of industrial revolution. For example, take the deep structural crisis which happened from 1873 to 1896. That was also a period of the second industrial revolution, the first one occurring in the early nineteenth century. The second industrial revolution involved electricity, petroleum, the automobile and the airplane. These are the technologies that dominated industrial development in the twentieth century. The current crisis started in 1971 with the end of Bretton Woods and the floating of the dollar. Along with the crisis, we have had a third industrial revolution, the basis of which is infomatics and biogenetics with all the dangers that it represents, as well as nuclear and space technology. By themselves those technologies are not enough to create the conditions of high growth, because growth depends on an equilibrium between the various social forces. During each of these periods, capital interests have exploited the industrial revolution to their own unilateral benefit. Because an industrial revolution also means that old industries are decaying, labor loses the advantages of collective stability and becomes more vulnerable. Therefore capital is in a position to erode whatever rights the working classes have conquered in the previous period. That's what's happening now. Along with an industrial revolution there is growing brutality, inequality - not just between capital and labor, but between a variety of workers - and an overall vulnerability of the working classes. As long as capital is able to mobilize unilaterally and use the industrial revolution to its exclusive benefit, it is not able to move out of the crisis. We can also compare the atmosphere now to the atmosphere during what was called the belle epoch at the beginning of the twentieth century. That 15-year period was after a long crisis and before World War I. During the course of that time the discourse was exactly what we hear today - that the unilateral rule of capital is going to benefit everybody. It was a period of the weakening of the working classes. The movement of the socialist parties to the right - like Tony Blair and Gerhard Schroeder, etc. - is exactly similar to the move to the right of the socialist parties at the beginning of the 20th Century. For exactly the same reasons. Nairobi slum. I am not suggesting that the industrial revolution per se is or is not the basis of growth. It could be if social and political conditions established a better balance of forces - less unilaterally favorable to capital. That is one dimension. Another dimension is how it works in different parts of the world. Particularly, for example, the U.S. vis-a-vis Europe and Japan. It is true that today's discourse, especially in the United States, stresses the relatively higher rates of growth. But this growth is socially unbearable in the longer run. It goes along with a growing inequality and with a growing vulnerability that the American working class will not accept indefinitely. It is also artificial and at the expense of others. The success of the U.S. is proportionate to the lack of success elsewhere, particularly in Europe and Japan. This means that the so-called U.S. hegemony is very vulnerable. In the nineteenth century, Britain, which was hegemonic at that time, had an enormous export surplus which was the counterpart of its ability to export capital. It was financing railways in Argentina and India, etc. If we look at the pattern of current globalization and U.S. hegemony, we find exactly the opposite. The U.S. balance of trade is in an enormous deficit, which means that hegemonic power is (draining) capital from other parts of the world. Who is funding that? The whole world, but especially the Europeans and Japanese. I don't think that they will accept that indefinitely. This doubles the vulnerability of the so-called high growth in the United States. MM: Andre Gunder Frank has argued that developing countries may benefit most when there is stagnation or contraction in the center countries. What is your perspective on that in the current period? Arvin: I am a friend of Andre Gunder Frank and we agree on many things, but I am cautious about those kind of sweeping generalities. I think everything depends on class struggle and not on whether we are in an A phase or a B phase. Development changes are unequal throughout the world, because the balance of social and political forces are not similar from one place to another. During the current period of crisis, not all of the countries of the Third World have suffered. Major countries, including China, to a lesser degree India, southeast Asia, Korea and Taiwan and if you add up their populations, you get more than half of the world - have not suffered from the crisis. They have had high rates of growth because they were less subject to the rule of globalization than others. They have controlled their own move into the global system. We could discuss whether they have been democratic or not, but the domestic ruling class has, to a certain degree, been in control. We saw the exact opposite in Africa, the most vulnerable part of the Third World, where the local ruling classes do not control anything and where as a result the rates of growth are zero if not negative in some cases. Therefore we see that the differences in the same period depend on the capacity of the local ruling class - bourgeois capitalists in various shapes and forms - to control its relation to the global system. MM: You write that structural adjustment is not misguided but a part of the management of the crisis in the rich countries. What do you mean by that? Arvin: Structural adjustment as it is imposed by the World Bank and IMF on most countries of the South and on the former socialist countries in eastern Europe and the Soviet Union is unilateral. That is, adjustment of the economies of those countries is to the needs of dominant capital. That means the needs of the triad - the U.S., the European Union and Japan - and nothing more. This structural adjustment is not structural but a conjunctural adjustment. It is one of the tools of crisis management - that is, finding an outlet for the surplus of financial capital. That is the root of the external debt of the Third World and former socialist countries. The effects are disastrous, as we can see in any part of the world other than in the dominant triad. What we need is another pattern of globaliza tion. The issue is not globalization or withdrawing from the world and going to the moon. There are many alternatives. Globalization could be conceived as a pattern of regulated expansion of the markets at the international level, of channeling the surplus of capital towards productive investments. That would be a pattern of globalization that I would call structural because it would help change structures. It would also be multilateral rather than unilateral, an adjustment of each part of the world to another pattern of globalization - what I call a multipolar pattern of globalization. MM: What is your perspective on calls for reforming the IMF to make it a "good"global regulatory institution? Amin: I think you cannot start from the top, by changing these international institutions. That would be very naive, because the international institutions reflect the imbalance of forces at that level. Things must start from below, from national societies. Again, it is the class struggle which is the key to understanding social change. Things must change at that level to the benefit of the working classes everywhere - in the U.S. as well as in Senegal. That means reinventing new forms of organization, of action, of legitimate targets, etc. It has deep social dimensions. That should be supported or enlarged by regional organizations. One can imagine that an average country in Latin America alone cannot go very far, but Latin America on the whole can. Similarly, no African country can go very far alone, but Africa as a whole could and can. Not to speak of India or China. To think about a move from the top is a little naive, as if there are no interests behind the system as it is. There are interests, of course, and they are the prevailing interests of transnational capital and the triad states that are behind them, as well as compradors in the Third World. MM: If developing countries were to form regional blocs, what would be the institutional structure of region-wide economic management? Amin: It must accomplished gradually. First, we must reinforce the complimentarity between the industrial and agricultural developments of the partners. And that needs much more than just a free trade area, because it needs some degree of planning-a word that is not fashionable today - of investment ot develop complimentarity with a view to reducing the monopolies of the West - monopolies in technologies, in communications and media, in the use of natural resources. But it also has a political dimension. It must gradually reinforce the capacity of those regions to ensure security, both internal and external security - not only in the police sense, but a security based on legitimate power, the whole question of democracy. It must also work toward regional security, that is, reducing the causes of conflict. We'll never have a world without conflict, but we can reduce the causes. MM: How would you see the regions relating to external forces, especially the rich countries? Amin: That is where it would lead to institutional changes in the U.S. We have had this in the past during the decade after World War 11, during that period of high growth, when we had negotiations at the global level, however weak. It was a time of UNCTAD [the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development]. There were negotiations on the transfer of technologies, etc. We need not have a remake of that, but a revival of its spirit. This would give back a role to the UN in serious international negotiations on those issues. I don't want to be overly optimistic, but I think the last meeting of UNCTAD in Bangkok is indicative of a move in this direction. We heard there a majority of states, most from the Third World, speaking against globalization as it is. MM: What would be the regional approach to capital flows from outside the region or trading outside the region? Amin: There are a number of principles. One is that so-called hot money flows - capital that wants to get a quick profit - should bi forbidden and countries should be allowed to establish exchange controls against that. Second, we should look at productive investment, including that by transnationals, on a caseby-case basis. Getting certain technologies is difficult without accepting private investment of foreign capital. But that could be negotiated. There we come back to a series of old questions, such as the control over the export of profit, control over the degree of using local inputs, the transfer of technology, property rights, etc. These are important points of the agenda. It's not fashionable today to speak of that, but these are objectively needed. During an interview, Samir Amin, the head of the Third World Forum in Dakar Senegal, discussed the stagnation of the world capitalist system, the renewal of growth in the US at much higher rates, and region-wide economic management. Copyright Multinational Monitor Apr 2000 Quellen:UMI MULTINATIONAL MONITOR 04/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 01Apr2000 USA: PAUL M. SWEEZY AT 90 A CELEBRATION.(surge of corporate profits through 1999 and into 2000). Ricardo Alarcon, Samir Amin, Nicholas Baran, Rosalyn Fraad Baxandall, Grace Lee Boggs, Anne Braden, Paul Buhle, Pablo Gonzalez Casanova, Noam Chomsky, Doug Dowd, Richard DuBoff, Barbara Ehrenreich, Bill Fletcher, Jr., John Bellamy Foster, Andre Gunder Frank, John Kenneth Galbraith, Martha Gimenez, Joan Greenbaum, Robert Heilbroner, Edward Herman, Michael Lowy, Harry Magdoff, Istvan Meszaros, Leo Panitch, Frances Fox Piven, Robert Pollin, Lukin Robinson, Annette Rubenstein, Pete Seeger, John J. Simon, Daniel Singer, William Tabb, Shigeto Tsuru Kalecki, teach things that Marxist political economists should view as essential? Another disagreement is over the role of monopoly and competition. How central is the concentration and centralization of capital to our understanding of the workings of capitalism today-a full century after Marxists and other radicals first raised the question of monopoly capitalism? Whatever one's abstract theory is-and all theories by definition rely on a degree of abstraction-its usefulness lies in its capacity to make sense of everyday reality, while providing the strategic analysis necessary for practical revolutionary solutions. Throughout its history, MR has advanced a theoretical view known as monopoly capital or stagnation theory. This perspective, outlined in Baran and Sweezy's Monopoly Capital, argued that Marx's "law of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall" was no longer directly applicable to the monopoly capitalist economy that emerged at the beginning of the twentieth century, and had to be replaced by a "law of the tendency of surplus to rise"-where surplus was defined as the difference between the wages of production workers and total value added. A key contradiction of capitalism in its monopoly stage is therefore that of rising surplus and the associated problems of surplus absorption. [1] Rising surplus and the accumulation of a mountain of surplus means that capitalist firms are faced with the problem of how to employ all of it, i.e., how to use the piled-up cash to make more profit. True, capitalists can use or waste some of this surplus for personal pleasure. But that is peanuts compared to the size of the growing surplus. So the problem remains one of how to absorb all of the surplus actually and potentially available. Generally, the answer is sought in new investment, but that expansion of capital comes up against consumption limits imposed by the distribution of income: who will buy the increased volume of output? New epoch-making innovations-resembling the steam engine, the railroad, and the automobile in the overall effect on accumulation-could conceivably provide sufficient profitable investment outlets, but such epoch-making innovations are historical rather than economic factors that cannot be counted on to appear when needed or on the scale necessary in terms of surplus absorpti on. Even the astounding new field of computer/digital technology has so far absorbed only a small part of the massive economic surplus hanging over the economy. Foreign investment, which once provided an outlet for surplus, has become an efficient device for the transfer of surplus from the periphery to the core of the capitalist system, thereby further compounding the problem. All of this means that the system has a powerful tendency towards stagnation, arising from an inability to find outlets for all of the surplus actually and potentially generated at the level of production-a problem partly (but only partly) compensated for by the rise of various countervailing factors, such as the growing sales effort, military spending, and financial expansion. Like all theoretical perspectives this one has to be put to the harsh test of reality, and modified where necessary to explain changing historical conditions. In what follows, I will attempt to show concretely, by focusing on current historical developments, why I believe this general approach is vital to the explanation of economic conditions today-at the beginning of a new millennium. The Party The first thing one notes, in turning to those accounts that dominate today's business news, is that corporations are awash in rising profits. In the final months of 1999, the business press was euphoric as it became clear that "the party"-referring to the current period of extraordinarily high profits-would continue past the millennial turning point into the year 2000. In its quarterly profits scoreboard in mid-August, Business Week declared that "Corporate America's profits are cruising at warp speed [ldots] Profits for the 900 companies on Business Week's Corporate Scoreboard rose a merry 28% during this year's second quarter, the best performance since 1996's final period." What was fueling the expansion in the late recovery phase of the business cycle, the same magazine had declared two weeks before, was the fact that corporations were awash in cash, with 851 billion dollars in retained earnings. In December 1999, word was out in the business community that the U.S. economy was exiting "the millennium with an unprecedented bang." [2] Needless to say, the big bash occurring at the economic pinnacle of the society is an exclusive affair. The growth of wealth at the top, as Business Week told its corporate readers, has been accompanied by a relative decline in income and wealth shares at the bottom-with little in the way of any real income gains among wage earners at present. A Harris poll at the end of 1999 showed that most of the U.S. population believe that they have not benefitted from what is now, according to the National Bureau of Economic Research, the longest business cycle upswing in the nation's history, ongoing since March 1991-hardly a surprising result, with real wages still "barely budging," and only about a fifth of the population owning stock market assets outside of retirement funds. "The biggest fault line," Business Week declared in its December 27, 1999 issue, [ldots] seems to be between Americans who are getting an extra income boost from the stock market or a dot.com employer, and everybody else. Indeed, the most striking development in the New Economy for many has been the end of the 40-hour week: Americans now log more hours on the job than workers in any other industrialized nation. But growth in real hourly compensation has dropped from a 4.3% annual rate in the third quarter of 1998 to 2.3% this year [ldot] This may explain why 51% of Americans feel cheated by their employer, according to a new study from Opinion Research Corp., International. Indeed, Business Week warned its corporate readers, the 52 percent of the population who, in the same Harris poll, registered sympathy with the protesters in Seattle were responding to real economic grievances, and the protests could soon migrate in a big way from streets to workplaces. Monopoly Capital and the Tendency of Surplus to Rise The contradictions of the economy, however, are far more acute than a mere perusal of the business press would lead one to believe, and relate to the entire development of accumulation under monopoly capitalism. One way in which to begin to understand the conditions now confronting the U.S. economy is to look more concretely at the economic surplus being generated by the society. An item-by-item accounting of total economic surplus, incorporating all of the relevant components from official government estimates of national income and output, is a difficult undertaking which obviously cannot be attempted here. Nevertheless, in a extremely simplified version of such an analysis, corporate profits plus depreciation plus net interest can be taken as a first approximation of the actual economic surplus-one which, however, leaves out many elements that properly belong to surplus, such as expenditures on marketing, now running at more than one trillion dollars a year. [3] When we look at the trends in economic surplus, measured in this limited way, we discover that the share of surplus in total output is increasing. The average annual percentage of profits plus depreciation plus net interest of corporate business in Gross Domestic Product (GDP) rose from 14.2 percent between 1946 and 1973 to 14.7 percent between 1974 and 1998. Further, corporate profits plus depreciation plus net interest a s a percentage of GDP soared to their highest level ever in 1997 at 16.6 percent-rising for the first time since the Second World War above 16.1 percent, the level reached in 1929 (the year of the Great Crash), and surpassing the Second World War peak of 16.5 percent in 1942. [4] This strongly suggests that the problem of rising surplus has in no way lessened in recent decades, and remains endemic to monopoly capitalism as it enters the new millennium. The strength of the tendency of surplus to rise can be traced historically, as we have seen, to changes that occurred as the system evolved from its freely competitive to its monopoly phase-that is, to the shift from an economy consisting largely of small family-based firms to one dominated by large monopolistic (or oligopolistic) enterprises. Competition begets monopoly and monopoly begets competition-but in an historically evolving pattern. Competition, rather than simply disappearing under monopoly capitalism, became in some ways more intense. Competition over productivity and innovation-the drive to obtain the low cost position-only stepped up its pace. New dominant forms of competition also arose, especially those associated with marketing-targeting, product development, advertising, and sales promotion. Yet, in areas of price, output, and investment, modifications took place in the nature of competition as a result of the concentration and centralization of capital-sharply distinguishing monopoly capitalism from the freely competitive age that preceded it. With the rise of the giant firm, price competition ceased to take place in any significant sense within mature monopolistic industries-as opposed to new industries in which a shakedown process is occurring (such as computers and digital technology in general), and industrial sectors that resemble the firms of the earlier competitive stage. [5] Megacorporations tend to price corespectively, as Joseph Schumpeter said, in a process of indirect collusion, acting as price-makers rather than price-takers. Prices for manufactured products in mature monopolistic markets tend to go only one way: up. Hence, inflation (whether double-digit or at more moderate levels) has come to characterize monopoly capitalism. Price deflation, once fairly normal for capitalism, l argely disappeared in mature industries and at the aggregate level in the system as a whole with the rise of the regime of big business. [6] And this is true despite the fact that prices for raw materials, particularly from the third world, have had a tendency to be depressed (indeed to be caught up in deflationary spirals)-a function of the workings of the imperialist system. The decline of price competition in the system as a whole has its counterpart in the change in the way in which output and investment are determined. Rather than lower prices in the face of a shortfall of demand as in a freely competitive economy, the typical giant firm tends to take up the slack by lowering its output and increasing its level of excess productive capacity in order to protect profit margins (the mark-up on prime production costs). As a result, investment, which is governed by expectations, tends to be regulated much more by the level of excess capacity-and by expected profits on new investment in plant and machinery if this capacity were to be expanded-than by anything else. Empirical studies have consistently shown that it is only when capacity utilization rises to 85 percent in the economy as a whole that national investment is spurred; but this process is a self-limiting one, since new investment means the growth of additional manufacturing capacity, which must find a market-investment itself then tends to lead eventually to idle capacity. In this strange, semi-regulated world of monopoly capital, there is no longer a life-or-death competition threatening the survival of the mature capitalist enterprise (though mergers in search of greater monopoly power are a common occurrence). Rather, the giant corporations that dominate the contemporary economy engage primarily in struggles over relative market share. Although conventional economics textbooks still tell us that the existence of a perfectly competitive economy guarantees that economic profits are short-lived or nonexistent, in the real world of late capitalism, large firms not only obtain persistent profits, but there is a hierarchy of profit rates between firms. It remains a competitive world for corporations in many respects, but the goal is always the creation or perpetuation of monopoly power-that is, the power to generate persistent, high, economic profits through a mark-up on prime production costs. [7] The Generation and Absorption of Surplus Since the intent here is to explain how the growth of monopoly capital is related to such fundamental tendencies as rising surplus and economic stagnation, and how this generates various distortions in the way the capitalist economy is supposed to work (according to its own ideal conception), it is useful to turn to the work of the post-Keynesian economist Myron Gordon, who has developed an empirical analysis of the underlying pattern of accumulation, focusing on the ratio of value added to the wages of production workers. [8] Gordon shows that, while over the years 1899 to 1949 the ratio of value added to the wages of production workers in manufacturing in the United States fluctuated around 2.50, between 1949 and 1994 it rose fairly steadily to 5.25, more than double its 1949 value. [9] What this means is that there is a growth in the ratio of surplus to the wages of production workers as determined at the level of production. The shift in the employment structure of manufacturing firms, from one that was geared primarily to the employment of production workers to one in which production workers are vastly outnumbered by nonproduction workers, is closely associated with this rising surplus within production and with the pursuit of monopoly power and profits. At the beginning of the twentieth century, Gordon notes, manufacturing firms [ldots] were engaged primarily if not solely in production. By the end of the century their primary activity had become the pursuit of monopoly power. The large modern corporation incurs the costs of a wide range of nonproduction activities for the purpose of maintaining and increasing its monopoly power. Hence, they may be called monopoly activities. The objective of monopoly power is to increase the margin of price over production cost for the firm's products and to increase the sale of the products at these prices. These activities include research and development for the purpose of improving existing products, discovering new products, and reducing production costs. They include selling and advertising to increase sales and the markup of price over production costs. They include labor relations to persuade or intimidate workers to produce more or accept lower wages. They include political contributions, lobbying and corruption of government officials in order to obtain natural resource s on favorable terms and other favors of government. They include the employment of lawyers, accountants, and financiers to avoid and evade taxes and to influence tax legislation. I could go on. These activities may be harmless apart from their cost and their consequences for the distribution of income. They may be beneficial to the degree that productivity is raised, or they may be malignant in their consequences for society. In any event, what they all have in common is the pursuit of the profits to be gained from monopoly power. [10] In addition to expenditures on the pursuit of monopoly power as such, there are also of course expenditures which can be seen as disguised profits-such as the enormous income (including reserves for severance and pensions) set aside for top management. Although treated as "cost deductions" before profits are calculated, these returns are obviously part of the economic surplus-indeed the lavish rewards to top corporate officers and their hangers-on may be largely returns for the successful pursuit of monopoly power, the immediate goal of today's "strategic management." "Monopoly workers" are defined by Gordon as all employed workers minus production workers, and thus are equivalent to nonproduction workers. [11] Between 1899 and 1949, the number of monopoly workers increased at more than twice the rate of that of production workers. From 1949 to 1994, the growth of production workers was stagnant (falling at the end of the period), while the average annual growth rate for monopoly workers was around 2 percent. A concrete example of the radical changes taking place in this respect in large corporations can be seen in the case of Microsoft. In fiscal year 1997, Microsoft had a total sales revenue of 11.4 billion dollars, while its labor and material costs of production were only 1.1 billion dollars. (Research and development was 1.9 billion dollars, sales and marketing 2.9 billion dollars, general administration 362 million dollars, and gross profits before taxes 5.3 billion dollars.) Prime production costs (the labor and materials costs of production) thus accounted for less than 10 percent of sales revenue, while profits made up 47 percent of sales revenue. The remainder was accounted for by the costs of the pursuit of monopoly power. The 5.3 billion dollar profit was earned with a total investment in equipment, inventory, and buildings of less than 2 billion dollars. [12] Microsoft may seem like an extreme example-but as the leading high-tech corporation in the world, it also reflects the extreme direction that capital is taking in general. Moreover, the phenomenon is not simply confined to computer software firms or dot.coms. Nike, to take an additional case, subcontracts nearly all of its production to owners of factories in China, Indonesia and Vietnam. Tens of thousands of workers in Asia employed by these subcontractors produce the shoes sold by Nike, which is thus free to devote almost its entire paid employment to the pursuit of monopoly power. In 1992, Nike's payroll included eight thousand people globally, almost all of whom were in management, sales promotion, and advertising-geared to Nike's swoosh label products. The economic surplus generated by these means is enormous, as are the costs of Nike's pursuit of monopoly power. In 1992, Michael Jordan received twenty million dollars from Nike for promoting its shoes. This was as much as the entire payroll of the four Indonesian factories involved in the production of Nikes, where the mainly female workers sometimes earned as little as fifteen cents an hour while working eleven hour days. By 1996, conditions for these workers had improved only slightly; twenty-five thousand workers produced seventy million pairs of shoes annually (each of which sold for between forty-five and one hundred dollars in North America) and received an average of 2.23 dollars per day, while often being compelled to work six hours overtime. In Vietnam, where Nike was subcontracting much of its production by the late 1990s, conditions were even worse. In 1997, most of the thirty-five thousand workers in Vietnam producing Nikes were women who worked twelve hour days for a labor cost of two dollars per pair of shoes. Under attack for the labor conditions in the factories that make its shoes, Nike has responded that it is simply a marketing company, uninvolved in production. In the words of its vice-president for Asia, "We don't know the first thing about manufacturing. We are marketers and designers." [13] Nike is an extreme example, mainly because of the extent of its outsourcing and subcontracting of production. In most manufacturing, direct investment in production is deemed vital, since the capacity to generate economic surplus is rooted in production, and in innovations occurring at this level. Nonetheless, the general shift in the overall economic emphasis of firms from production to marketing and finance has been central to the evolution of the large firm throughout the past century. As early as 1939, in a Federal Trade Commission Inquiry, General Motors revealed that a Chevrolet selling for 950 dollars had production costs of around 150 dollars while the remainder went to marketing, distribution, and profits. [14] Mergers and Financial Speculation The economic surplus generated by firms, according to the foregoing analysis, is enhanced by the pursuit of monopoly power and the pursuit of monopoly power generates its own costs, which increasingly dominate the balance sheets of firms. The expenditures associated with the pursuit of monopoly power are not reducible to the sales effort, but also include the absorption of surplus through such means as corporate mergers and financial speculation. As economic surplus expands, so do corporate mergers, which have as their object the pursuit of higher degrees of monopoly power through the concentration and centralization of capital. Hence, economic surplus that could be used for investment is instead used up in the buying and selling of firms-a competitive race that takes on more and more urgency as it becomes more global in character. The two greatest merger waves in history are those associated with the opening and the close of the twentieth century. "Measured relative to the size of the economy," according t o the Economic Report of the President, 1999, "only the spate of trust formations at the turn of the century comes close to the current level of merger activity," with the value of mergers and acquisitions in the United States in 1998 alone exceeding 1.6 trillion dollars. Corporate mergers and acquisitions grew at a rate of almost 50 percent per year in every year but one between 1992 and 1998. Globally, more than two trillion dollars worth of mergers were announced in the first three quarters of 1999. [15] The leading sectors in this merger wave have been in high technology, media, telecommunications, and finance but mega-mergers are also occurring in basic manufacturing. It is not simply the quantitative extent of mergers and acquisitions that matters but also their type and purpose. Many of these mergers, as noted in the Economic Report of the President, are "synergy-seeking mergers" in which large corporations are seeking to take advantage of "economies of scope" by moving into closely related markets. Further, while the great merger wave at the beginning of the twentieth century was directed mainly at control of an overwhelming share of domestic markets by three or four firms, the merger strategy of today has shifted to consolidating a substantial share of international markets through: (a) establishing production facilities in other industrialized countries (where the biggest markets are to be found), and (b) cross-border buyouts and mergers. The merger in 1998 of Daimler Benz and Chrysler to form a 130 billion dollar company, DaimlerChrysler, which Business Week called "the first global car colossus," is a case in point. It was an attempt to consolidate a global market position in an industry where there "there is plant capacity to build at least 15 million more vehicles each year than will be sold." According to McGraw-Hill business analysts, such consolidation within the auto industry worldwide is inevitable, with the number of leading auto companies in the world expected to drop by half, from forty to twenty, in the opening decades of this century. [16] The DaimlerChrysler merger was followed last year by Ford's acquisition of Volvo. Moreover, the globalization of monopoly capital in the auto industry is stepping up its pace. According to The Wall Street Journal of February 14, 2000, The world's two biggest auto companies are about to enter a bidding war for an insolvent South Korean car maker-and the outcome could determine who will be No. 1. Ford Motor Co. intends to take on General Motors Corp. in the auction of Daewoo Motor Co., Ford Chairman W. Wayne Booker confirmed over the weekend, ending weeks of speculation about Ford's plans. GM set the auction in motion when it offered around $6 billion for most of Daewoo's assets. People close to the situation say DaimlerChrysler AG also is seriously considering jumping in. A DaimlerChrysler spokesman wouldn't comment. Why are the world's biggest car makers so keenly interested? At first glance, Daewoo Motor seems hardly worthy of such attention. It owes sixteen billion dollars it can't repay, has car factories in some of the world's oddest corners, and its American marketing arm even publishes a brochure that opens with the question, "Dae-who?" But the contest is one for world domination. Ford's string of 1990s acquisitions-capped by its purchase a year ago of Volvo Cars Ltd.-has positioned it to overtake GM for global auto-making leadership. Whichever company gets Daewoo Motors' annual worldwide capacity of about two million cars will have the potential to be the biggest. Despite the fact that the current merger frenzy, as the above example dramatically demonstrates, is directed at global rather than national markets, the underlying aim remains a familiar one. As Michael Mandel, economics editor of Business Week, declared in October 1999, "The old market verities apply: As concentration increases, it's easier for remaining players to raise prices. In the copper industry, the prospect of consolidation helped drive up future prices by more than 20% since the middle of June." [17] What is now the greatest merger wave in capitalist history is rapidly transforming the global competitive environment. Already by the mid-1990s, the largest three hundred corporations in the world accounted for 70 percent of foreign direct investment and 25 percent of world capital assets. The top ten telecommunications firms now control 86 percent of a 262 billion dollar world market-and analysts expect the number of giant telecommunications firms controlling that world market to be halved early in this century. The rivalry between giant firms is being intensified at the transnational level as corporations seek to carve out larger and larger world market territories. [18] The underpinnings of the current massive merger wave can be understood much more fully by examining the way they are financed. Although it is still frequently claimed in textbook economics that the main purpose of both the issue of new stock and borrowing by nonfinancial corporations is to finance investment in productive capacity, this is far from the case. In the 1980s, U.S. corporations borrowed heavily, not in order to finance real investment (which they continued to pay for out of gross profits), but for the purpose of stock buybacks (to boost the value of their shares) and takeovers. This borrowing was thus geared to the speculative purchase of existing assets with the expectation of expanding capital gains, and, in the case of takeovers, the creation of new monopolistic positions through "synergy." In the 1990s, the diversion of corporate funds to Wall Street has intensified, but firms have relied on their own profits increasingly for this purpose rather than debt (though also continued to borrow as a defensive strategy against hostile takeovers). The speculative bubble associated with the internet and the Nasdaq in particular had created such an out-of-this-world situation, by the opening month of 2000, that the digital giant America Online (AOL) was able to purchase Time Warner, in a 183 billion-dollar deal that constituted the biggest (though still pending) merger in all of history. And AOL was able to do so despite the fact that it had only 20 percent the annual revenue and 15 percent of the workforce of Time Warner. [19] Increasingly, we are faced with a world economy governed by financial speculation and the attempt to create global monopoly (or oligopoly) power-led by media and telecommunications and fanning out through all sectors of production. In this shift to a more global playing field, there is the likelihood of increasing currency and trade wars between capitalist blocs, even as core capital attempts to head off trouble by establishing new rule-making bodies at the international level, such as the World Trade Organization (WTO). Real power, however, lies not with such transnational rule-making bodies (which can never become an "international of capital"), but with the actual states and corporations. The United States and World Competition In this age of globally expanding circuits of capital, the United States has for the most part been able to set the pace. The source of this U.S. advantage resides not simply in the special role of the dollar; its military power; the ability of its corporations to position themselves strategically in global markets so as to obtain spectacular mark-ups (evidence of monopoly power); or its position as a haven for foreign capital-but also in the low rate of increase in unit labor costs (i.e., nominal hourly compensation per unit of output) of U.S. manufacturing relative to manufacturing in the other capitalist states. This can be seen in Table 1 (below). With exception of the United States and Canada, all of the G-7 countries had double-digit rates of increase in exchange-rate adjusted unit labor costs from 1985 to 1990. Moreover, in the 1990 to 1998 period, the exchange-rate adjusted rate of increase in unit labor costs in the United States remained lower than those of its two biggest competitors: Japan and Ge rmany. Unit labor costs are a more comprehensive indicator of international competitiveness than labor productivity growth rates, which they partly reflect. Hence, it is the relatively slow growth of unit labor costs in the United States, Bureau of Labor Statistics analysts tell us, that point to the decisive advantage gained by the United States in overall competitive position over its major competitors in the period after 1985. [20] There can be little doubt about where the ultimate source of this advantage lies: in the effectiveness of the class struggle against labor in the United States. According to one study, real after-tax hourly compensation of production workers in the U.S. economy dropped by almost 14 percent between 1977 and 1995. [21] The present expansion has been accompanied by increasing attacks on unions; growth of "nonstandard employment" (in which part-time and other contingent employment constitutes a bigger and bigger portion of total employment); longer work hours; and cutbacks in state spendi ng for human welfare. In this battle to lower the floor, U.S. capital has played the leading role and its major competitors are increasingly moving in the same direction. The same general process taking place in the U.S. economy is occurring globally on a much larger, more polarized scale. What Harry Magdoff noted in The Age of Imperialism as far back as 1969 is even more apparent today (though it now applies to the giant firms of numerous states): "It is the professed goal of these international firms [U.S. multinationals] to obtain the lowest unit production costs on a world-wide basis. It is also their aim, though not necessarily openly stated, to come out on top in the merger movement in the European Common Market and to control as large a share of the world market as they do of the United States market." In fact there is an "essential oneness" to the U.S. economy and its foreign economic policy. According to the dominant corporate consensus, the struggle against domestic labor is at one with the struggle with other capitalist blocs, and with the struggle against already superexploited third-world labor. In each and every case, the goal is a narrow pursuit of low producti on costs, widening profit margins, increased capital gains, and global monopoly power-at the expense of all other interests and values. [22] It goes without saying that this "essential oneness" in the accumulation drive of the system at all levels at the beginning of the twenty-first century conceals its own internal antagonisms. The anti-WTO protests in Seattle may signal the fact that the "party" for capital at this historical juncture is nearly over-in more ways than one. NOTES (1.) Paul A. Baran and Paul M. Sweezy, Monopoly Capital (New York: Monthly Review Press, l966), p. 125. It should be emphasized that in referring to "the tendency of surplus to rise" Baran and Sweezy had no intention of presenting this as an iron law, i.e., one not subject to countervailing factors that modify or mitigate its effect. Rather they invariably emphasized that this was a mere tendency (or tendential law), which could not be examined apart from such countervailing factors. (2.) Business Week, August 16, 1999, pp. 88-90, August 2, 1999, pp. 28-31 and December 27, 1999, pp. 52-55. (3.) Kevin J. Clancy and Robert S. Shulman, Across the Board (October 1993), p. 38, and Marketing Myths that are Killing Business (New York: McGraw Hill, 1994), pp. 140, 171. (4.) National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, vol. 1, Tables 1.1 and 1.16; and U.S. Commerce Department, Survey of Current Business, vol. 79, no.8 (August 1999), pp. D2 and D5. I would like to thank my friend and colleague Michael Dawson for the initial analysis of this data. It should be noted that depreciation is sometimes seen as a cost to be deducted before arriving at net profits, but in practice depreciation (the amount of which is enormously increased by accelerated depreciation allowances) is part of the social accumulation fund (or total economic surplus) available to capital and hence needs to be included in the surplus. In other words, the appropriate categories for analysis of accumulation are gross profits, gross savings/surplus and gross domestic product (all of which include depreciation) rather than net profits, net savings, or net national product. For more detailed discussion of these issues as well as a far more comprehensive empirical treatment of the tendency of the surp lus to rise see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "The Tendency of Surplus to Rise, 1963-1988," in John B. Davis, ed., The Economic Surplus in Advanced Economies (Brookfield, Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 42-70. A heavily abridged version of this research was published under the same title in Monthly Review, vol. 43, no. 4 (September 1991), pp. 37-50. For a graph of this data showing the tendency of the surplus to rise, see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "Is There an Allocation Problem?: Accounting for Unproductive Labor," Science & Society, vol. 58, no. 3 (Fall 1994), p. 323. (5.) Both monopolistic and competitive sectors of the economy continue to exist side by side, but the giant corporation, able to control to a considerable extent its level of price, output, and investment, is the typical firm in a dynamic sense in the monopoly capitalist economy. Noting the difference in price structure in monopolistic and competitive industries, the Natural Resources Committee report, The Structure of the American Economy (1939), directed by Gardiner Means, observed that the term "monopoly" could be "used on the whole to refer to situations in which sufficient control would be exercised over price by an individual producer or by a colluding group of producers to make possible monopoly profits, i.e., profits above the rate necessary to induce new investment in other industries not subject to monopoly control." Conversely, "a situation was in general classified as competitive if there was insufficient control over price to make monopoly profits possible." Gardiner Means, ed., The Structure of the American Economy, Part I (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1939), p. 139. (6.) See Harry Magdoff, "A Note on Inflation," in John Bellamy Foster and Henryk Szlajfer, ed., The Faltering Economy: The Problem of Accumulation Under Monopoly Capitalism (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1984), pp. 118-23. The Great Depression was of course an exception to the inflationary tendencies under monopoly capitalism. (7.) Competition, which has as its main goal the development of monopoly power (entailing surplus profits or monopoly rents) through the monopolization of particular technologies and markets, is sometimes known as "Schumpeterian competition" and closely corresponds with how the term "competition" is used within business today. See James Galbraith, Created Unequal: The Crisis in American Pay (New York: The Free Press, 1998), pp. 40-42. (8.) Myron Gordon, "Monopoly Power in the United States Manufacturing Sector, 1899 to 1994," Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, vol. 20, no. 3 (Spring 1998), pp. 323-25. Gordon's analysis is inspired by Michal Kalecki's concept of the "degree of monopoly," defined as the price mark-up over average prime production costs. On the relation of Kalecki's analysis to that of Baran and Sweezy see John Bellamy Foster, The Theory of Monopoly Capitalism (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1986). (9.) Gordon, "Monopoly Power," pp. 323-25. The production workers category, upon which much of Gordon's analysis depends, is described in the Census of Manufactures as follows: "This item includes workers (up through the line-supervisor level) engaged in fabricating, processing, assembling, inspecting, receiving, storing, handling, packing, warehousing, shipping (but not delivering), maintenance, repair, janitorial and guard services, product development, auxiliary production for plant's own use (e.g., power plant), recordkeeping, and other services closely associated with production operations at the establishment covered by the report. Employees about the working-supervisor level are excluded from this item." General Summary, Census of Manufactures, 1992, p. A-1. Like most economic statistics there are some conceptual issues raised by the production workers category, which have to he taken into account in its application, such as the fact that it excludes all of those managers supervising production above t he line-supervisor level (including these among nonproduction workers). Nevertheless, it draws an important distinction between those production workers directly engaged in the process of producing use values and those nonproduction workers primarily geared to management, marketing and finance, etc. (10.) Gordon, "Monopoly Power," pp. 326-27. (11.) There are some theoretical difficulties in equating the "nonproduction workers" category with the concept of "monopoly workers." For one thing, monopoly power is normally rooted in production, so that production workers are also, in a sense, monopoly workers. But Gordon's intention is clearly one of emphasizing that production workers are caught up in the stringent capitalist logic of increasing productivity, and at the same time keeping down unit labor costs-in other words raising the rate of exploitation-in contrast to nonproduction (or "monopoly") workers who have as their main task the increase of the mark-up. (12.) Ibid, pp. 327-28. (13.) Richard J. Barnet and John Cavanagh, Global Dreams (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1994), pp. 325-28; Walter LaFeber, Michael Jordan and the New Global Capitalism (New York: W.W. Norton, 1999), pp. 106-07, 147-48; David Korten, The Post-Corporate World: Life After Capitalism, 1999), pp. 77-78. (14.) On General Motors see Douglas Dowd, The Waste of Nations (Boulder: Westview Press, 1989), pp. 65-66. This example of course doesn't take account of the fact that the sales effort had actually penetrated into the production process of such large firms, as Veblen and later Baran and Sweezy were to argue, so that incorporated into production costs themselves were the costs associated with frequent model changes-accounting for perhaps a third of all production costs in automobile production by the middle of the last century. See Baran and Sweezy, Monopoly Capital, pp. 131-38. (15.) Economic Report of the President, 1999, p. 39; Korten, The Post-Corporate World, p. 42; New York Times, January 19, 1998, p. A1; Michael J. Mandel, "All These Mergers are Great But[ldots]," Business Week, October 18, 1999, p. 48. (16.) "The First Global Car Colossus," Business Week, May 18, 1998, pp. 40-41. (17.) Mandel, "All These Mergers," p. 48. (18.) Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "Virtual Capitalism," in Robert W. McChesney, Ellen Meiksins Wood and John Bellamy Foster, ed., Capitalism in the Information Age (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1998), pp. 53-54; United Nations, Human Development Report (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999), p. 3. (19.) Doug Henwood, Wall Street (New York: Verso, 1997), pp. 72-75; Business Week, January 24, 2000, p. 37. (20.) U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, A BLS Reader on Productivity, Bulletin 2474 (April 1996), p. 12. (21.) Eric A. Nilsson, "Trends in Compensation for Production Workers, 1948-1995," Review of Radical Political Economics, vol. 31, no. 4 (December 1999), pp. 133-63. (22.) Harry Magdoff, The Age of Imperialism (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969), p. 200. On the concept of the "essential oneness" of U.S. accumulation see Harry Magdoff, Imperialism: From the Colonial Age to the Present (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1978), p. 239. Average Annual Rates of Change of Unit Labor Costs in Manufacturing, G-7 Countries: U.S. Dollar Basis 1985-1990 1990-1998 U.S. 1.6 0.2 Japan 10.8 1.3 Germany (West) 15.9 0.3 France 11.6 -2.0 United Kingdom 11.4 1.8 Italy 14.4 -2.3 Canada 7.1 -2.3 Source: United States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, "International Comparisons of Manufacturing Productivity and Unit Labor Cost Trends, 1998," News, August 27, 1991, Table B, p. 11. The employment compensation component of unit labor costs includes both direct and indirect payments to employees. Direct payments include wages and salaries (also encompassing compensation to corporate executives), vacation pay, tips, bonuses, etc. Indirect payments include employer contributions to legally required insurance programs and contractual and private benefit plans, including social insurance funds, private pensions, and health and welfare plans, and workers' compensation for injuries. Monthly Review, Vol.51, No.11 COPYRIGHT 2000 Monthly Review Foundation, Inc. (c) 2000 Information Access Company. All rights reserved. This article may only be stored on a computer network for a maximum of 30 days. Quellen:IAC MAGAZINE DATABASE MONTHLY REVIEW 01/04/2000 P1 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 18Jan2000 INDIA: THE STATESMAN (INDIA) - The Raj Effect. Essays on Colonialism, By Bipan Chandra, Orient Longman The monograph under review comprises a number of essays dealing with various aspects of colonialism, primarily in the context of India's historical experiences. Though a number of essays had previously been published in a number of well known international journals, it does not diminish the importance of the monograph. The author at the very outset has reminded his readership that the analysis of colonialism and its impact generally had a bearing on policy making in matters related to developmental issues in post colonial societies. Bipan Chandra convincingly argues that there is hardly any dearth of historical data, which would refute the view of some well known pundits that underdevelopment of colonial societies was primarily a direct fallout of pre-colonial backwardness. The author negates the views of some well known intellectuals, who look upon colonialism as an agent of modernisation. Chandra, in a number of essays, has attempted to interpret colonialism from the stand point of domination, exploitation and underdevelopment of one society by another. More importantly, he is inclined to hold the view that a discussion on colonialism need not necessarily devote much attention to pre-colonial social structures, since colonialism inevitably transforms it into an essential part of a new colonial structure which in turn is subsumed by the world capitalist system. The author lucidly narrates the development and popularity of coherent critiques of colonialism, as developed by Indian nationalists particularly in the last decades of the previous century. However, it was in the early decades of the twentieth century that colonialism as a discipline of study attracted the attention of Western academics. In India, several nationalist minded economists such as Kumar Ghoshal, K T Shah, O N Vakil, Bal Krishna Wadia, along with some others, were amongst the first to approach the issues related to colonialism on the basis of both theoretical and empirical approaches. Significant contributions also came from Marxist intellectuals, like Rajani Palme Dutt, the author of the well known India Today and then by A R Desai in his Social Background of Indian Nationalism. But, throughout the twentieth century, much of the Western intellectual exercises on colonialism betrayed a cynicism towards the Marxian understanding on the subject. The 1950s witnessed a spurt of publications on the subject and the researches of Clifford Geertz on Indonesia and Mohammad Husain's work on Egypt attracted world wide attention. However, the high point of researches on colonialism was still to arrive. The Cuban revolution, the national liberation struggles in Algeria and Vietnam, and the spread effect of anti-imperialist and popular movements in Latin America, heralded a new dawn for academics well versed in Marxist theories on the subject. Several academics, both leftists as well as centrists by conviction made important contributions particularly in the realm of "dependency theory". Men like Andre Gunder Frank, Celso Furtado and Paul Baran inspired intellectuals like Amiya Bagchi, Hamza Alavi, Samir Amin, Jairus Banaji, to mention a few, to carry out high quality researches on colonialism. The author has strongly argued that the development of agrarian relations in th colonies notably in Indonesia, Egypt and in parts of Latin America provide interesting examples of transformations or changes set in motion by colonialism. Chandra in this context argues that the semi-feudal structure of agrarian relations that prevailed in 19th century India was not a carry over from the Mughal period. In essence, it was the result of two gigantic attempts to transform the pre-colonial agriculture into a capitalist one. However, since this was done under colonial conditions, it inevitably resulted in a semi-feudal agriculture dominated by the colonial state, world capitalist market, landlords, merchants and money lenders. Thus, alongside semi-feudal features of an agrarian society bourgeois property relations, commercialisation and other elements of capitalist agriculture came to co-exist. The author has consistently argued that the Marxian explanations of the impact of colonialism on non-Western societies suffered from a few weaknesses. While on one hand there had been little effort to study the colonial reality in depth, on the other, the contradictions within the societal frameworks dominated by industrial capitalist metropolises were also not brought to the surface. In other words, Chandra reaches the conclusion that Marx and many of his latter day followers failed to realise that though capitalism was a single world system and colonies were its basic constituents, the latter did not become capitalist in the same way the metropoles did. In the first and third essays of the monograph, Chandra has succinctly argued that the colonial state was a mechanism that hardly granted a space for the accommodation of the interests of indigenous social classes. The colonial state, therefore, subordinated the indigenous social categories to the whims of the metropolitan capitalist class. As a result, the upper sections of the dominated society were denied an opportunity to share political power with the ruling alien elite. In one of the essays entitled "A Colonial India: British versus Indian Views of Development", Chandra dwells extensively on the nationalist critique of the economic drain resulting from the colonial policies in India. In the critique developed by men like Dadabhai Naoroji, Chandra argues, the drain was defined as the unilateral transfer of funds from India or that part of transfer of wealth or commodities from India to England, for which India received no equivalent economic, commercial or material returns in any form whether in the present or in the future. The drain in the opinion of the nationalists, thus resulted in a major loss of capital for India. On the other hand, it was a major source of capital accumulation for Great Britain and played a large part in the rapid industrialisation of that country. Therefore, Chandra points out, it was not surprising to find men like MG Ranade and GV Joshi placing strong demands for tariff protection for India's infant industries. At the same time they pleaded for direct government support to industry and agriculture. In brief, the nationalists had reached the conclusion that there was a contradiction between the logic of colonialism as propounded by the British and the interest of the Indian masses. The author has dealt with several other important issues. For instance Chandra has distinguished three district stages, during which the forms and patterns of subordination and surplus extraction underwent changes in consonance with the development of capitalism as a world system. Chandra has also dealt with the transition of India from a colonial to an independent postcolonial economy. The author makes it clear that no real development is possible in the third world, unless the former colonies break away from the world capitalist system and embrace socialism. However, since Chandra has limited his discussion till the early 1980s, he stands in no position to evaluate the changes set forth by privatization and globalization in the context of the developing and underdeveloped economies. At the same time, his emphasis on the "independent capitalism" as pursued by Congress in the decades following the independence, also leaves a few questions to be answered. While the Congress role in eliminating semi-feudal conditions in the agrarian sector could be doubted, the radicalism of the left remained out of tune, at times, with historical and economic developments. Despite such mild criticism it has to be conceded that the monograph brings together a priceless collection of essays, displaying the author's intellectual expertise. Chandra provides strong evidence that the Indian economy since the colonial period, by virtue of a number of linkages, was steadily appropriated into the world capitalist model. The author's contribution is immensely significant as in recent times, transnational corporations are aiming to establish a new type of subordination which strengthens the logic of world capitalism. RAJ SEKHAR BASU All Material Subject to Copyright Copyright 2000: The Statesman (India). All Rights Reserved. Quellen:ASIA INTELLIGENCE WIRE THE STATESMAN 18/01/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 01Jan2000 GUATEMALA: Guatemala in the global system. By Chase-Dunn, Christopher. With the signing of peace accords in 1996 ending Latin America's longest and bloodiest civil war, Guatemala opened a new chapter in its history, one in which a new and inclusive political community might finally emerge. For scholars, such an era of potential societal normalization and democratization is a propitious opportunity to reconsider how a more inclusive and multiethnic national community could emerge and how Guatemalans might respond to the changing forces of economic, ideological, and geopolitical globalization. The end of the Cold War, powerful global market forces, changing foreign policies in the developed countries, the emergence of stronger multilateral agencies at the world level, and the current hegemony of neoclassical policy prescriptions emanating from powerful global agencies-all these factors pose significant challenges as well as possible opportunities for Guatemalan democratization and development. Guatemala is the largest country in Central America and was the last to negotiate an end to civil war. In many ways, Guatemala's social problems are representative of those in many other parts of the Third World. Poverty and discord among ethnically different populations appear in many developing countries. Guatemala is not among the world's poorest countries; on the basis of gross national product per capita, it falls into the category the World Bank terms "low-to middle-income countries." But among countries in this category, Guatemala has one of the highest economic disparities between rich and poor. It has valuable national resources but also unusually high un-and underemployment. The tax rate relative to the gross domestic product is very low. In this context, the peace process created an important opening. Formerly excluded groups have ostensibly been invited to participate in legal and institutional processes for formulating policies of development and democratization. The prospect of a new, multiethnic nation that recognizes the cultural, political, and economic rights of its poorest and least powerful citizens is more of a real possibility now than it has been for many decades. Guatemala's accord on Identity and Rights of Indigenous Peoples, one of the peace accords, for example, is a conceptual breakthrough that many other countries should emulate. Comparing the social changes in developing countries of Asia, Africa, and Latin America is important for understanding particular countries such as Guatemala, as well as for comprehending the global system as a whole. The situation of a developing country emerging from a long period of strife suggests comparisons with other specific countries-El Salvador and Nicaragua-but also South Africa and the countries of the Middle East. These cases of struggle and partial reconciliation need to be compared and placed in the historical context of decolonization and national liberation movements (see Arnson 1999). Along similar lines, democratization and development policies in Guatemala cannot be adequately understood without considering the worldwide waves of democratization (Markoff 1996), as well as important changes in the world economy. The trajectory of the East Asian economies raises the question of whether development models that have worked there would be entirely appropriate for Guatemala. It also suggests possibilities for eventual Guatemalan involvement in Pacific Rim linkages. Guatemalan economic, political, and cultural change has long been importantly affected by the actions of powerful states and firms in the developed countries, especially the United States. The actions of U.S.-based firms and political-military interventions at important historical points have had a major impact on Guatemalan society, as well as on other Central American countries. The demise of the Soviet Union and the emergence of global patterns of economic restructuring have produced a hegemonic consensus regarding the necessity of producing for the global market and courting foreign investment. This ideological perspective has been reinforced by the policies of powerful multilateral agencies, such as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF). But economic and ideological globalization have also been accompanied by a long-term trend toward greater international and transnational political organization and integration and the slow emergence of global governance (Murphy 1994). The United Nations has played an important role in the Guatemalan peace process. International organizations of indigenous peoples, labor unions, women's movements, and movements for environmental protection have begun to play important roles in the politics of every country. These movements are part of a process of political and social globalization that is emerging in tandem with, and in response to, economic and cultural globalization. The problem of Guatemalan development in context thus requires that we understand the current period in long-term perspective and in wide geographical circumstance, both nationally and globally. The possible results for Guatemala could be not only part of, but potentially active in shaping, the future of the larger world society. How the relationship between the developed and the developing countries is worked out in the next decades will be a major determinant of the nature of the twenty-first century world-system. Guatemala is a node for our understanding of these emerging structures. The theoretical perspective that is best suited to such a temporally deep and spatially broad analysis is the world-systems perspective (Shannon 1996). The world-systems approach looks at human institutions over long periods of time and employs the spatial scale necessary for comprehending whole interaction systems. It is neither Eurocentric nor core-centric, at least in principle. The main idea is simple: human beings on Earth have been interacting with one another in important ways over broad expanses of space since the emergence of oceangoing transportation in the fifteenth century. Before the Americas were incorporated into the Afroeurasian system, many local and regional world-systems (intersocietal networks) held sway (see Blanton et al. 1992). These were inserted into the expanding European-centered system largely by force, and the surviving populations of indigenous Americans were mobilized to supply labor for a colonial economy that was repeatedly reorganized according to the changing geopolitical and economic forces emanating from the European and, later, North American core societies. This whole process can be understood structurally as a stratification system composed of economically and politically dominant core societies (themselves in competition with one another) and dependent peripheral and semiperipheral regions. Some of these have succeeded in improving their positions in the larger core-periphery hierarchy, while most have simply maintained their relative positions. This structural perspective on world history allows us to analyze the cyclical features of social change and the long-term trends of development in historical and comparative perspective. We can see the development of the modern world-system as driven primarily by capitalist accumulation and geopolitics, in which businesses and states compete with one another for power and wealth. Competition among states and capital is conditioned by the dynamics of struggle among classes and by the resistance of peripheral and semiperipheral peoples to domination from the core. In the modern world-system, the semiperiphery is composed of large and powerful countries in the Third World (for example, Mexico, India, Brazil, China) and smaller countries that have reached intermediate levels of economic development (such as the East Asian newly industrialized countries). It is impossible to understand the history of social change in the system as a whole without taking into account both the strategies of the winners and the strategies and organizational actions of those who have resisted domination and exploitation. It is also difficult to understand how innovative social change emerges without a concept of the world-system as a whole. As with most earlier regional intersocietal systems, new organization forms that transform institutions and that lead to upward mobility most often emerge from societies in semiperipheral locations. Thus, all the countries that became hegemonic core states in the modern system had formerly been semiperipheral. This is a continuation of a long-term pattern of social evolution that has been called "semiperipheral development" (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997). Earlier semiperipheral conquest states and semiperipheral capitalist city-states acted as the main agents of empire formation and commercialization for millennia. The pattern includes the semiperipheral communist states and probably will also comprise future organizational innovations in semiperipheral countries that may transform today's global system. The world-systems approach requires that we think structurally. We must be able to abstract from the particularities of uneven development the structural continuities. Today, the core-periphery hierarchy remains, though some countries have moved up or down (see Chase-Dunn and Grimes 1995). The interstate system also remains, though the internationalization of capital has perhaps further constrained states' ability to structure national economies. States have always been subjected to larger geopolitical and economic forces in the world-system, and, as is still the case, some have been more successful at exploiting opportunities and protecting themselves from liabilities than others. In this perspective, many of the phenomena that have been called globalization correspond to recently expanded international trade, financial flows, and foreign investment by transnational corporations and banks. The globalization discourse generally assumes that until recently there were separate national societies and economies, and that these have now been superseded by an expansion of international integration driven by information and transportation technologies. Rather than a wholly unique and new phenomenon, however, globalization is primarily international economic integration, and as such it is a feature of the world-system that has been increasing for centuries (Chase-Dunn et al. 1999). The Great Chartered Companies of the seventeenth century were already playing an important role in shaping the development of world regions. Certainly, the transnational corporations of the present are much more important players, but the point is that "foreign investment" is not an institution that has become important only since 1970 (or since World War II). Giovanni Arrighi (1994) has shown that finance capital has been an important component of the commanding heights of the world-system since the fourteenth century. The current floods and ebbs of world money are typical of the late phase of very long "systemic cycles of accumulation." TYPES OF GLOBALIZATION The discourse about globalization has used the term to mean several different things. For some writers, globalization means a new stage of global capitalism that is qualitatively different from an earlier stage that recently ended, though how it allegedly differs varies from author to author (Chase-Dunn 1998, chaps. 3, 4). This essay will distinguish between two main meanings of the term globalization: international integration and the political-ideological discourse of global competitiveness. Globalization as international integration needs to be further denoted as international economic integration, international political integration, and international cultural and communicative integration. Of course, each of these subtypes has many aspects; but the point is that international integration relates to the extent and intensity of links in a set of global networks of interaction. We can determine empirically how economically integrated were the societies on Earth in the late nineteenth century and how "economically globalized" the world economic network is now (Chase-Dunn et al. 1999). This question is separable from people's sense of their linkages with one another. Economic globalization is both a long-term trend and a cyclical phenomenon. If we calculate the ratio of international investments to investments within countries, the world economy had nearly as high a level of "investment globalization" in 1910 as it did in 1990 (Bairoch 1996). Similarly, if we calculate the ratio of total world international exports to the sum of all the country GDPs, there was a very high peak of "trade globalization" just before World War I, with a rapid decrease thereafter until 1950 and then a slow rise to the current very high level of trade globalization. Globalization as international economic integration therefore should be understood as part of a long-term set of processes that have characterized the world-system for centuries and, arguably, continue to describe the system in the current period of global capitalism (Chase-Dunn 1998, xiv-xvi). The cyclical trend of international economic integration needs to be understood in the context of those other cycles and trends. They imply that future struggles for economic justice and democracy need to learn from earlier struggles in the world-system context. While some populists have suggested that progressive movements should again employ the tools of economic nationalism to resist the powers of the "global princes of capital" (Moore 1996; Mander and Goldsmith 1996), others contend that political globalization of popular movements will be required to create a democratic and collectively rational global commonwealth (Robinson 1998-99). THE GLOBALIZATION PROJECT The term globalization has been used in a different way to refer to "the globalization project"-the abandonment of Keynesian models of national development and a new emphasis on deregulation and opening national commodity and financial markets to foreign trade and investment (McMichael 1996). This use points to the ideological aspects of the most recent wave of international economic integration. The term I prefer for this turn in global discourse is neoliberalism. The worldwide decline of the political left may have predated the revolutions of 1989 and the demise of the Soviet Union, but it was certainly also accelerated by these events. The structural basis of the rise of the globalization project is the new level of integration reached by the global capitalist class. The internationalization of capital has long been an important part of the trend toward economic globalization, and many claims to represent the general interests of business have been made-indeed, by every modern hegemon. But the real international integration of interests of the capitalists in all parts of the system has reached a level greater than ever before. This is the part of the model of a global stage of capitalism that must be taken most seriously, though it can certainly be overdone. The world-system has now reached a point at which both the old interstate system, based on separate national capitalist classes, and new institutions representing the global interests of capitalists simultaneously exist and wield power. In this light, each country can be seen to have an important ruling class fraction that is allied with the transnational capitalist class. Neoliberalism began as the Reagan-Thatcher attack on the welfare state and labor unions. It evolved into the IMF's structural adjustment policies and the triumphalism of global business after the demise of the Soviet Union. In U.S. foreign policy, it has found expression in a new emphasis on "democracy promotion." Rather than propping up military dictatorships in Latin America, the emphasis has shifted toward coordinated action between the CIA and the U.S. National Endowment for Democracy to promote electoral institutions there and in other semiperipheral and peripheral regions (Robinson 1996). Robinson points out that the kind of "low-intensity democracy" that is promoted is really best understood as "polyarchy," a regime form in which elites orchestrate a process of electoral competition and governance that legitimates state power and undercuts more radical political alternatives that might threaten their ability to maintain their wealth and power by exploiting workers and peasants. Robinson convincingly argues that polyarchy and democracy promotion are the political forms most congruent with a globalized and neoliberal world economy in which capital is given free rein to generate accumulation wherever profits are greatest. Globalized capital, moreover, has been explicitly constructed to out-maneuver the institutional contraints that had emerged from labor unions, socialist parties, and welfare states, as well as economic nationalism and socialist institutions in the periphery and semiperiphery. Certainly, new incarnations of those older strategies will emerge in the future as marginalized, dominated, and exploited peoples learn to resist the new globalized forms of control. Indeed, some older ideas that may have been ahead of their time may now come into their own. For example, labor internationalism had become a tired phrase used as a fig leaf for Soviet imperialism; but a new wave of labor internationalism will probably be the only rational response to the latest wave of the globalization of capital. The women's movement and the environmental movement have already developed new transnational organizational structures, and such an approach is also emerging among the indigenous peoples of the world (Wilmer 1993). These new transnational "antisystemic movements" (Amin et al. 1982; Arrighi et al. 1989) can be described as globalization from below. Alliances among different groups can organize together across borders based on their common desire to confront neoliberalism and global capital. Thus global capital creates, for the first time, the real historical possibility for an Earthwide antisystemic political alliance that can build a more humane and sustainable world society. THE SPIRAL OF CAPITALISM AND SOCIALISM The interaction between expansive commodification and resistance movements can be denoted as "the spiral of capitalism and socialism" (Boswell and Chase-Dunn 2000). The spiral metaphor describes how capitalism and socialism feed each other's growth and organizational forms. Capitalism spurs socialist responses by exploiting and dominating peoples, and socialism spurs capitalism to expand its scale of production and market integration and to revolutionize technology. The historical development of the communist states can be explained as part of a long-term, spiraling interaction between expanding capitalism and socialist counterresponses. The Russian and Chinese revolutions were socialist movements in the semiperiphery that intended to transform the global logic of capitalism but ended up using socialist ideology to mobilize industrialization for the purpose of catching up with core capitalism. Defined broadly, socialist movements are those political and organizational means by which people try to protect themselves from market forces, exploitation, and domination, and to build more cooperative institutions. The several industrial revolutions, by which capitalism has restructured production and reorganized labor, have stimulated a series of political organizations and institutions created by workers to protect their livelihoods. This happened differently under different political and economic conditions in different parts of the world-system. Skilled workers created guilds and craft unions. Less-skilled workers created industrial unions. Sometimes these coalesced into labor parties that played important roles in supporting the development of political democracies, mass education, and welfare states (Rueschemeyer et al. 1992). In other regions, workers and peasants were less politically successful, but managed at least to protect access to rural areas or subsistence plots for a fallback or hedge against the insecurities of employment in capitalist enterprises. To some extent, the burgeoning contemporary "informal sector" in both core and peripheral societies provides such a fallback. The mixed success of workers' organizations also had an impact on the further development of capitalism. In some places, workers or communities successfully secured higher wages or protected the environment in ways that raised the costs of production for capital. When this happened, either capitalists displaced workers by automating them out of jobs, or capital migrated to places where fewer constraints allowed cheaper production. The process of capital flight has been an important force behind the uneven development of capitalism and the spreading scale of market integration for centuries, as capitalism has grown ever more international and the size of firms has increased. International markets became more and more important to successful capitalist competition. Fordism, the employment of large numbers of easily organizable workers in centralized production locations, was partially supplanted by "flexible accumulation" (small firms producing small, customized products) and global sourcing (the use of substitutable components from broadly dispersed competing producers). These new production strategies made traditional labor organizing approaches much less viable. Socialists were able to gain state power in certain semiperipheral states and to create political mechanisms for protection against competition with core capital. This was not a wholly new phenomenon; capitalist semiperipheral states had done similar things. But the communist states claimed a fundamentally oppositional ideology, in which socialism was allegedly a superior system that would eventually replace capitalism. The content of the ideology may make some difference for the internal organization of states and parties, but every contender must be able to legitimate itself in the eyes and hearts of its cadre. The claim to represent a qualitatively different and superior socioeconomic system is not evidence that the communist states were ever able to become structurally autonomous from world capitalism. The communist states severely restricted the access of core capitalist firms to their internal markets and raw materials, and this constraint on the mobility of capital was an important force behind the post-World War II upsurge in the spatial scale of market integration and a new revolution of technology. In certain areas, capitalism was driven to further revolutionize technology or to improve living conditions for workers and peasants because of the demonstration effect of propinquity to a communist state. U.S. support for state-led industrialization in Japan and Korea (in contrast to U.S. policy in Latin America) is only understandable as a geopolitical response to the Chinese revolution. The existence of "two superpowers"-one capitalist and one communist-in the period since World War II provided a fertile context for the success of international liberalism within the "capitalist" bloc. This was the political-military basis of the rapid growth of transnational corporations and the latest round of "time-space compression" made possible by radically lowered transportation and communication costs (Harvey 1989). This technological revolution has once again restructured the international division of labor and created a new regime of labor regulation called "flexible accumulation." The communist states' long reintegration into the capitalist world-system took place because they could not compete with the new form of capitalist regulation. Thus capitalism spurs socialism, which spurs capitalism, which spurs socialism again in a wheel that turns and turns while getting larger. As trends in the last two decades have shown, austerity regimes, deregulation, and marketization in nearly all the communist states occurred during the same period as similar phenomena in noncommunist states. The synchronicity and broad similarities between Reagan-Thatcher deregulation and attacks on the welfare state, austerity socialism in most of the rest of the world, and increasing pressures for marketization in the Soviet Union and China are all related to the B-phase downturn of the Kondratieff wave, as were the moves toward austerity and privatization in most semiperipheral and peripheral states.1 The trend toward privatization, deregulation, and market-based solutions among parties of the left in almost every country has been thoroughly documented by Lipset (1991). Nearly all socialists with access to political power have abandoned the idea of doing anything more than buffing off the rough edges of capitalism. The pressures of a stagnating world economy may affect national policies differently from country to country, but the ability of any single national society to construct collective rationality is limited by its interaction with the larger system. The most recent expansion of capitalist integration, termed "globalization of the economy," has made autarchic national economic planning seem anachronistic. Yet political reactions against economic globalization are now under way in the form of revived ex-communist parties, economic nationalism, and a growing coalition of popular forces that are critiquing the ideological hegemony of neoliberalism (see Mander and Goldsmith 1996). IMPLICATIONS FOR GUATEMALA From the ground in Guatemala, it must appear that most of the global view as described above is a dream of someone who lives on the moon. The enormous problems of everyday life for the vast majority of Guatemalans and the hectic pace of political events in the struggle to implement the peace accords make it hard to consider the broad sweep of history or the possibilities for constructing a more egalitarian and sustainable world-system. Nevertheless, a historical understanding of the dynamics of global capitalist development is necessary to comprehend current developments and future possibilities. What can we expect of the world-system in the next 50 years that will be relevant to Guatemala? Having been in in a K-wave downswing (B-phase) since the late 1960s, the world economy is now entering an upswing, or A-phase, in which relative rates of economic growth will generally be higher. The fiscal pressures on states will ease; labor will be in demand. The possibilities for mobilizing workers and peasants to demand higher wages and better working conditions should be greater than heretofore because firms and states will be more willing to make compromises to keep business running smoothly. There is also a downside to this trend. The rate of ecological degradation will increase as more resources are used in production. Late in K-wave upswings, when states have abundant resources, is the point when wars occur among core states (Goldstein 1988). If the economic hegemony of the United States continues to decline in comparision to competing core powers (Germany, Japan, China), the world will enter a dangerous window of vulnerability to core warfare in the 2020s (Chase-Dunn and Podobnik 1999). Catastrophic environmental disaster could be another possibility. These portents should concern progressive movements everywhere. The slow emergence of a world state will create the possibility for the democratization of global political institutions. Popular movements could act to block global state formation, but they might alternatively struggle to build democratic and collective rationality into the new global institutions. The hypothesis of semiperipheral development suggests that the most transformative institutional innovations and the most powerful challenges to capitalism will come from semi-peripheral regions in the world-system. Mexico is the most obvious candidate that has direct relevance for the Guatemalan situation. This said, a country such as Guatemala, with its human and natural resources, could also be a fertile ground for transformational action, especially in an age of global politics. In many ways, the smaller countries have a greater interest in the unexplored terrain of "globalization from below."2 Most recent interpretations of Central American history paint a picture of each country with its own complicated and tumultuous experience, leading by different paths to the same happy result: democracy (for example, Paige 1997). A world-systems perspective produces a different portrait. The Central American countries have all been repeatedly restructured by world market forces and geopolitics. The landed colonial patricians were displaced by the agroexporters (who ruled in alliance with the military), and these, in turn, have been partially supplanted by a new transnational elite of neoliberals who seek to link the national economies more tightly with core capital and global markets. It is fascinating to compare the nineteenth-century liberal ideology and policies of the Central American agroexporting elites (science, reason, privatization of communal resources) with more recent neoliberal ideology and policies-competitiveness, fiscal austerity, deregulation, and privatization. Both liberalism and neoliberalism in Central America were and are combinations of imported ideas and local adaptations that justify and facilitate new forms of exploitation and outmaneuvering of rivals. Popular movements emerged during the twentieth century in Mexico and Central America in response to authoritarian rule, agrarian restructuring, and grinding poverty, but the timing of these movements has varied from country to country, depending on the shifting coalitions of elites and the changing nature of agrarian class relations in different regions. The actions and reactions of local rulers and the interventions of the United States have been influenced by the sequencing of rebellions and revolutions in Central America, Latin America, and the rest of the world. The Guatemalan nationalist movement after World War II and the U.S. intervention to overthrow the elected government of Jacobo Arbenz in 1954 (Gleijeses 1991) was distinctive in its timing. The other Central American countries had their popular upsurges and repressions in the late 1920s and 1930s. John Markoff's 1996 and 1998 studies of waves of democratic movements and institutional inventions show that these occurred on an interactive world stage rather than in isolation in each country. This also needs to be said of the revolutions of the twentieth century. Both the rebels and the forces that sought to defeat them learned much from previous efforts elsewhere. The world-systems perspective encourages us to see both the uniquenesses of particular political situations and the overall picture of twentieth-century resistance and repression. One irony of the differing sequences is the current situation in southern Mexico and the quite different situation across the border in Guatemala. After 30 years of civil war, Guatemalans are tired of killing and want to make the peace work, while in southern Mexico a long-dormant situation, the Chiapas struggle for land ownership, has heated up. William Robinson (1996, 1998, and in this issue) sees the emergence in each Central American country of a new ruling class fraction of the domestic elite that represents the interests of global capitalism; this transnational elite promotes neoliberal policies and openness to global investment. Robinson contends that the outcome of the 1980s struggles was a system of elite-controlled elections in which this transnational elite gained the greatest share of power. This analysis is substantially accurate, but the Central American countries have important differences that must be considered. One is the difference in movement-repression sequences. More significant, as Robinson points out, is that the strength of the neoliberal fraction varies substantially from country to country, and is perhaps weakest in Guatemala. It is also important to realize that the neoliberal domestic elite may sometimes have interests that contradict the policies of the neoliberal international organizations, such as the World Bank and the IMF. On these issues, the domestic neoliberals may join the older landed elites in a common cause to defend Guatemalan "sovereignty" against the meddling of the international financial institutions (IFIs) and the UN. Nevertheless, although it now controls the presidency, Guatemala's neoliberal transnational elite is not very powerful against the older agroexporters and the military, at least in comparison with the other Central American countries and Mexico. The original Guatemalan "liberals"-the agroexporting elite-are reluctant to pay income taxes, so the Guatemalan government must fund itself mainly by extracting revenues from the poor by means of consumption taxes. The old ruling families have found enough allies to prevent a tax reform that would put the state on a firmer fiscal basis. Without such a reform, even neoliberal development projects have little hope of success. The issue of tax reform is one in which at least some of the domestic neoliberals may have more in common with the landed elites than with their transnational class allies as represented by the IFIs. On a visit to Guatemala in 1997, then IMF director Michael Camdesus explicitly stated the need for tax reform in Guatemala to put the state on a sound fiscal foundation. The Consultative Group (a subcommittee of the Group of Seven, the elite club of most-developed core countries) has used its financial leverage (based on a huge commitment of loans and grants for development projects) to try to move the implementation of the peace accords forward (Ruthrauff 1998). The Guatemalan case bears other important distinctions. The existence of both poor ladinos (mestizo or culturally hispanic) and a large group of indigenous people (indeed, a majority of the population) has added a strong ethnic dynamic to intra-and interclass relations. This ethnic division among the poor has made it easy for the rulers to pit exploited groups against one another. This element also operates in southern Mexico, but it is much less important in the other countries of Central America. The prospect for a cross-border (Guatemala-Chiapas) Mayanist alliance that coordinates and cooperates with the global indigenist movement (Wilmer 1993) could be a powerful force in regional politics; but the importance of a strong working alliance between indigenous and ladino popular groups cannot be overemphasized. Indigenous identity needs to include a class analysis so that common interests between ladinos and Maya can be conceptualized and organized. The need for this reconciliation of sorts is underscored by the current upsurge in domestic crime. The Guatemalan revolutionary armed struggle that began in the 1960s was never strong enough directly to threaten the power of the central government, but it did stimulate a huge repressive effort supported by the CIA, in which the official armed forces received massive resources and recruited large numbers of poor young men from both the ladino and Mayan regions. This method of suppressing the revolt provided an avenue of employment and security that is, ironically, contracting since the peace accords. This is probably the most important cause behind the current outbreak of kidnapping and robbery. GLOBALIZATION FROM BELOW, OR DELINKING? Labor movements in Guatemala have already partially succeeded in forging new implementations of the old notion of labor internationalism and in mobilizing support from the United States and other core countries based on concerns about human rights and the labor provisions of international trade agreements (Frundt 1987; Armbruster 1998). The problems of cross-border labor organizing and international labor solidarity are great, but the new organizational terrain of global capitalism requires new strategies (Stevis 1998). Because the globalization project has abrogated social compacts between business and labor in core countries, especially the United States, there are new possibilities for cooperation among Latin American and U.S. workers and their organizations. John Sweeney, the president of the AFL-CIO, visited the leaders of independent unions in Mexico City in 1997. This willingness to look at new alliances is a welcome relief from the longstanding Cold War approach to labor internationalism that was AFL-CIO practice until Sweeney's reform group took the leadership. Armbruster (1998) reports that help from the AFL-CIO was an important factor in the organizing success of the workers at the Phillips-Van Heusen plant in Guatemala. Women's movements in El Salvador have made important efforts to link their struggles with sympathetic groups in other Central American countries and in the United States. In Mexico, the resurgent electoral left, the agrarian movements in Chiapas and Guerrero, and independent trade unions have found that common opposition to neoliberalism is a uniting force. Some of Mexico's popular leaders have made an effort to mobilize support from the United States, but as yet, not many see this as part of a larger effort to democratize both Mexico and the global system. The emerging popular responses to globalization and neoliberalism face an important and potentially divisive issue. One possibility for mobilizing against global capitalism is "delinking" and self-reliance. Another, very different approach is to respond to global capitalism by building global democracy. The world-systems perspective has much to offer in considering the value of these options. The neoliberals have pronounced withdrawal from the capitalist world economy as unthinkable, and many popular leaders seem to agree. The wonders of technology and communications are alleged to be the highest prizes, and only by playing the game of competitiveness can a developing country have access to these. But some critics are now questioning whether the "necessity" of openness to the global economy is worth the costs. This is a healthy response because it unmasks many of the ideological presuppositions of neoliberalism. People need housing, clean water, and healthy food; it is not necessary to be able to program the microwave oven from the car radio. Still, new information technologies can make it easier than ever to organize transnational movements. Maximum advantage needs be made of these while holding the light to justifications of submission based on alleged economic necessity. The notion that self-reliance is an anachronism needs to be examined in historical perspective. Protectionism and national mobilization of development have been useful and successful strategies in the past. The semiperipheral national societies that later became hegemons in the Eurocentered world-system (England, the United States) all utilized tariff protectionism and state-sponsored mobilization to move themselves up the value-added hierarchy. The communist states used self-reliance and socialist ideology to try to establish a new mode of accumulation, though they ended up trying hardest to catch up with core capitalism. The demise of the communist states is also alleged to prove the worthlessness of state planning and self-reliant economic nationalism. But the successful practice of upward mobility in the world-system demonstrates the value that state intervention and protection of certain activities can have (Evans 1995). These strategies in the communist states did indeed "work" in terms of industrialization and urbanization, though the utopias they were intended to forge did not actually result. Instead, capitalism expanded and reincorporated these semiperipheral challengers. Today, this picture of challenge and response needs to take in the higher degree of economic and political integration of the current world-system. It is undoubtedly costlier to drop out of a more integrated system than to drop out of a less integrated one, so the costs of going it alone have increased. These costs have always been higher for small countries, such as those in Central America. This is why small countries have a greater interest in cross-border cooperation among popular movements. But the institutions of nationalism and the existing rules of the interstate system make such cooperation difficult. Popular movements in Guatemala face the dilemma of whether to focus on local and national-level institutions and alliances or on international and global ones. Would it be more productive to gain a voice in the national state and to use national sovereignty to provide protection from global market and geopolitical forces, or to try to reform the world-system by promoting popular democracy? The national route has a long history and is supported by the existing institutions, while the international route is little understood and in great need of imagination. Global democracy can be defined abstractly, but what would it mean in practice? Globalization from below would mean choosing the international alternative. In practice, neither a purely national strategy nor a purely global one would work for Guatemala, or any other country in the contemporary context. So the real problem is to decide on the mix and to pursue coordinated and complimentary approaches. POLYARCHY AND BEYOND Robinson's analysis raises another issue in the Guatemalan situation. Guatemala has not yet really achieved polyarchy, let alone real democracy. Polyarchy, while it may be largely a smokescreen for continued domination and inequality, is undoubtedly better than rule by the military. The implementation of the peace accords has gone very slowly; some observers have wondered if the current government is seriously committed to the process (for example, Jonas, this issue). The main problem, though, is that the weak neoliberal elite fraction cannot afford to push too hard on the military or the agroexporting elite families. Opposition to neoliberal policies should also serve as a unifying strategy for different kinds of popular movements in Guatemala. Globalization from below, in concert with popular forces in other Central American countries and Mexico, would most naturally be organized around opposition to neoliberal policies and institutions. In Guatemala, however, it might make tactical sense for the popular forces to ally themselves with the transnational neoliberals and the IFIs in the short run, so as to obtain concessions from the agroexport dynasties regarding the fiscal strength of the state and demilitarization. The implementation of the peace accords has at least the possibility of establishing the trappings of an electoral democracy with popular participation. Under these conditions, the campaign against neoliberalism might need to be postponed. This does not mean that popular movements should keep quiet. I agree with Robinson that strong popular movements in Guatemala can provide the support that the global and local neoliberals need to push through peace accord implementation. Once electoral democracy with popular participation is firmly in place, the campaign against neoliberal policies can commence in earnest. In the meantime, the popular movements need to learn about the history of the world-system and the globalization project. This, and the pursuit of further international popular alliances, will make it possible for Guatemalans to benefit from, and contribute to, globalization from below. Global democracy begins at home. NOTES An earlier version of this article was presented at the National Science Foundation-sponsored conference on Guatemalan Development and Democratization: Proactive Responses to Globalization, March 26-28, 1998, Universidad del Valle, Guatemala. Thanks to Patricia Landolt, Susanne Jonas, John A. Booth, and Bill Robinson for their suggestions. 1. The Kondratieff wave (K-wave) describes a worldwide economic cycle with a period of 40 to 60 years in which the relative rate of economic activity increases (during "A-phase" upswings) and then decreases (during "B-phase" periods of slower growth or stagnation). 2. What is needed here is a strong linkage between the trajectory of the world-system and the situation in Guatemala today. The theoretical perspective presented above would be much more useful if it were combined with a world-system history and formal comparative analysis that looks at the last two hundred years in local, regional, continental, and global frameworks from the focal point of the Guatemalan people. This research needs to be done. In its absence, I present a commentary on the current situation that uses insights from the longterm, large-scale perspective presented above. REFERENCES Amin, Samir, Giovanni Arrighi, Andre Gunder Frank, and Immanuel Wallerstein. 1982. Dynamics of Global Crisis. New York: Monthly Review Press. Armbruster, Ralph. 1998. Cross-Border Labor Organizing in the Garment and Automobile Industries: The Phillips Van-Heusen and Ford Cuautitlan Cases. Journal of World-Systems Research 4: 20-41. http://csf.colorado. edu/wsystems/jwsr.html> Arnson, Cynthia J. 1999. Comparative Peace Processes in Latin America. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Arrighi, Giovanni. 1994. The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power and the Origins of Our Times. London: Verso. Arrighi, Giovanni, Terence K. Hopkins, and Immanuel Wallerstein. 1989. Antisystemic Movements. London: Verso. Bairoch, Paul. 1996. Globalization Myths and Realities: One Century of External Trade and Foreign Investment. In States Against Markets: The Limits of Globalization, ed. Robert Boyer and Daniel Drache. London: Routledge. 173-92. Blanton, Richard, Stephen A. Kowalewski, and Gary Feinman. 1992. The Meso- american World System. Review 15, 3 (Summer): 418-26. Binghamton, NY: State University of New York, Fernand Braudel Center. Boswell, Terry, and Christopher Chase-Dunn. 2000. The Spiral of Capitalism and Socialism: Toward Global Democracy. Boulder: Lynne Rienner. Chase-Dunn, Christopher. 1998. Global Formation: Structures of the World-Economy. 2d ed. Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield. Chase-Dunn, Christopher, and Bruce Podobnik. 1999. The Next World War: World-System Cycles and Trends. In Bornschier and Chase-Dunn 1999. 40-65. Chase-Dunn, Christopher, and Peter Grimes. 1995. World-Systems Analysis. Annual Review of Sociology 21: 387-417. Chase-Dunn, Christopher, and Thomas D. Hall. 1997. Rise and Demise: Comparing World-Systems. Boulder: Westview. Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Yukio Kawano, and Benjamin Brewer. 1999. Economic Globalization Since 1795: Waves of Integration in the Modern World-System. Paper presented at the International Studies Association annual meeting, Washington, DC, February 20. http://csf.colorado.edu/ wsystems/archive/papers/c-d&hall/isa99b/isa99b.htm> Evans, Peter. 1995. Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Frundt, Henry J. 1987. Refreshing Pauses: Coca-Cola and Human Rights in Guatemala. New York: Praeger. Gleijeses, Piero. 1991. Shattered Hope: The Guatemalan Revolution and the United States, 1944-1954. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Goldstein, Joshua. 1988. Long Cycles: Prosperity and War in the Modern Age. New Haven: Yale University Press. Harvey, David. 1989. The Condition of Postmodernity. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell. Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1991. No Third Way: A Comparative Perspective on the Left. In The Crisis of Leninism and the Decline of the Left: The Revolutions of 1989, ed. Daniel Chirot. Seattle: University of Washington Press. 183-232. Mander, Jerry, and Edward Goldsmith, eds. 1996. The Case Against The Global Economy, And For a Turn Toward the Local. San Francisco: Sierra Club Books. Marer, Paul, Janos Arvay, John O'Connor, and Dan Swenson. 1991. Historically Planned Economies: A Guide to the Data. Washington, DC: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (World Bank), Socioeconomic Data Division and Socialist Economies Reform Unit. Markoff, John. 1996. Waves of Democracy Social Movements and Political Change. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press. -.1998 From Center to Periphery and Back Again: The Geography of Democratic Innovation. In Extending Citizenship, Reconfiguring States, ed. Michael Hanagan and Charles Tilly. Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield. 229-46. McMichael, Philip. 1996. Development and Social Change. A Global Perspective. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press. Moore, Richard K. 1996. On Saving Democracy: A Contribution to a Conversation About Global Praxis on the World-Systems Network (WSN). http://csf.Colorado.edu:70/00/wsystems/praxis/globprax> Murphy, Craig N. 1994. International Organization and Industrial Change: Global Governance Since 1850. New York: Oxford University Press. Paige, Jeffery M. 1997. Coffee and Power. Revolution and the Rise of Democracy in Central America. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Robinson, William I. 1996. Promoting Polyarchy: Globalization, U.S. Intervention, and Hegemony. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. -.1998. Neo-liberalism, the Global Elite, and the Guatemalan Transition: A Critical Macrosocial Analysis. Paper presented at the conference "Guatemalan Development and Democratization: Proactive Responses to Globalization," Universidad del Valle de Guatemala, Guatemala City, March 26-28. -.1998-99. Latin America and Global Capitalism. Race and Class 40, 2-3: 111-31. Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, Evelyne Huber Stephens, and John D. Stephens. 1992. Capitalist Development and Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Ruthrauff, John. 1998. The Guatemala Peace Process, the World Bank, and the Interamerican Development Bank. Paper presented at the conference "Guatemalan Development and Democratization: Proactive Responses to Globalization," Universidad del Valle de Guatemala, Guatemala City, March 26-28. Shannon, Thomas R. 1996. An Introduction to the World-System Perspective. Boulder: Westview Press. Stevis, Dimitris. 1998. International Labor Organizations, 1864-1997: The Weight of History and the Challenges of the Present. Journal of World-Systems Research 4: 52-75. http://csf.Colorado.edu/wsystems/jwsr.html> Wilmer, Franke. 1993. The Indigenous Voice in World Politics. Newbury Park, CA: Sage. Christopher Chase-Dunn is Distinguished Professor of Sociology and director of the Institute for Research on World-Systems at the University of California, Riverside. His Global Formation: Structures of the World-Economy was republished in 1998. He is coauthor (with Terry Boswell) of The Spiral of Capitalism and Socialism: Toward Global Democracy (2000). His current research examines the trajectories of economic and political globalization over the past two hundred years. Chase-Dunn presents a short summary of the world-systems perspective on globalization as relevant to considering the possibilities and probabilities of Guatemala's prospects for democracy and development. Guatemala's structural position in the larger global political economy is examined. Copyright Journal of Interamerican Studies Winter 2000 Quellen:UMI JOURNAL OF INTERAMERICAN TUDIES AND WORLD AFFAIRS 01/2000 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 21Aug1999 SINGAPORE: The advantage of economics. [CORRECTED] By Ho Kwon Ping. I OWE my degree in Economics to the Internal Security Department (ISD). When I completed my National Service in 1975 I decided to apply to the then University of Singapore (SU) as a mature student, since I had already studied three years in two other universities - Tunghai in Taiwan and Stanford in California. But I had to start all over as a freshman, which was rather boring, so I hardly attended classes and did only what was necessary to pass the exams. When I was detained by the ISD in 1977 just before the second-year exams, I was a pretty mediocre student, spending little time in lectures and most of my time as the Singapore correspondent of the Far Eastern Economic Review (as well as courting my then girlfriend and now wife, Claire Chiang). I half-expected to fail the upcoming exams. But the ISD intervened. I discovered that solitary confinement for two months focuses one's mind very well, and the ISD was kind enough to allow me to prepare for the exams. I ended up not only passing the exams but winning the Singapore Employers' Federation Medal for my scores. I would not, however, recommend this rather unorthodox way to do well in exams. Ever since my student activism days I had felt that economics was the solution to the problems of poverty, underdevelopment and exploitation. In Stanford, I was influenced by Prof John Gurley, a neo-Marxist economist who introduced me to the writings of Baran and Sweezy with their notions of monopoly capital, and Andre Gunder Frank and the dependency theorists. After I was thrown out of Stanford for my student activities, did my stint of National Service and enrolled in the Economics Department of the SU, I was a little older and wiser, but I still saw development economics as the panacea for the world's problems. I wanted to be an international civil servant working for the UN Conference on Trade and Development (Unctad) or similar pro-development institutions or writing on development issues. So I sent unsolicited articles to the Far Eastern Economic Review and eventually became its Singapore correspondent. I again landed into trouble, and after release from detention, just focused on my last year in SU. I chose not to do my Honours, and instead left Singapore with my new bride to be the economics editor of FEER in Hongkong. The four years in Hongkong, just-married but still childless and travelling all over the region writing on issues related to development economics, was one of the happiest periods of my life. I could examine the practice - or malpractice - of economics in real life. I even considered an academic career, and had actually accepted an offer to be a research fellow at INSEAD, the European business university. But my father suffered a stroke and I left journalism and a possible academic life to be a businessman. I have always felt that a grounding in economics is fundamental to understanding the world. One (perhaps the only!) of the few concepts which Marx got right, I think, is the notion that the economic substructure ultimately determines the shape of the socio-cultural-political superstructure. I would not advocate every young person to aspire to become an economist, but I would urge every student to study and understand basic economics. Unfortunately, I find that much of the teaching of economics in our junior colleges and universities is highly technical, and turns off young people before making them understand the "big picture" of the role of economics in world history and current events, and how economics underpins virtually every relationship - micro or macro, personal or institutional, international or global. Economics is actually an exciting subject - I was first drawn to it by Gunnar Myrdal's appropriately titled seminal book The Asian Drama - and look at the still unfolding political upheavals caused by arcane economic issues such as exchange rates and capital flows. But somehow economics lecturers and textbooks are very successful at making it into a dry and obscure subject which young people like my JC-age son find very heavy plodding. Hopefully, some of the excitement and drama - and indeed the inherent idealism behind the dismal science - of economics will be captured in the more creative pedagogy which should soon infuse our classrooms. In the new Singapore Management University which I chair, we hope to introduce to all business students compulsory courses in economics which will be less technical and more conceptual. In my own work today, most of the technical theories I learnt have been forgotten. But I have retained, almost as a way of thinking, fundamental economics concepts such as opportunity costs and trade-offs. They and other basic economics concepts shape the way I view the world. And it has been extremely useful - with an economics background and a regional journalistic experience, I find that wherever I consider making an investment in a new country, I first zero in on the macro-economic performance of the economy. That gives me a good feel of the investment climate before considering the specific project. If I had a choice to start all over again, would I still choose Economics as my degree subject? my son asked me the other day as we discussed his post-JC future. My answer was "yes". My life has taken me from aspiring to be an international civil servant or an academic, to actually becoming a journalist and then a businessman - but I know now that regardless of whatever I wanted to be or have become, my background in economics has given me a perspective with which to observe, analyse and understand the world around me. Properly taught, economics makes us understand the underlying relationships behind human behaviour and events. And armed with this understanding, we embark on any future career with an advantage. Mr Ho is president of the Wah Chang/Thai Wah Group. He is also chairman of Singapore Power, Singapore Institute of Management and Singapore Management University. (c) 1999 Singapore Press Holdings Limited. CORRECTION - AN article by Ho Kwon Ping headlined "The advantage of economics", reproduced in BT on Aug 21, omitted to mention that it first appeared in the July issue of Economics Newsletter, published by the National University of Singapore's Department of Economics. Mr Ho wrote it for the Distinguished Alumnus column. We are sorry for the omission. (STBT, 25/08/99) Quellen:BUSINESS TIMES (SINGAPORE) 21/08/1999 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 01Jul1999 USA: Looking back - Radical criminology and social movements. By Shank, Gregory. THE LAUNCHING OF CRIME AND SOCIAL JUSTICE (NOW SOCIAL JUSTICE) IN 1974 WAS a logical extension of the creation of alternative - some thought revolutionary - institutions that had their roots in the period spanning the late 1960s to 1975: the free universities, cultural expressions like the San Francisco Mime Troupe, the Bay Guardian, and research groups like the North American Congress on Latin America (NACLA) that bridged the academic and off-campus "Movement" worlds (the civil rights, Black and Chicano Power, antiwar, gay liberation, and feminist impulses that gave such research its political poignancy). 1 In that sense, even though Crime and Social Justice was the first radical criminology journal in the United States, it began appropriately without much fanfare. Yet the year itself was anything but unremarkable. In the popular culture, the jazz world lost Duke Ellington, Bob Dylan was "Tangled up in Blue" on his Blood on the Tracks album, Muhammad Ali danced like a butterfly and stung like abee, and Hank Aaron eclipsed Babe Ruth's home run record. Although the Students for a Democratic Society (SDS) had already self-destructed by splintering into a group promoting symbolic violence and another intent on democratic-centralist oblivion, college campuses were still highly politicized due to the war in Indochina. Nonetheless, academic repression was beginning to take its toll (disrupting the livelihoods of faculty members who were among the founders of the journal). The Black Panther Party had split over whether to achieve their goals via a peaceful electoral strategy promoted by Bobby Seale and Huey P. Newton or through Eldridge Cleaver's last-gasp revolutionism (before he opted for reactionary politics), and the Black liberation movement had become polarized between Marxist and cultural nationalist positions. The Native American armed occupation of Wounded Knee began in 1973, but FBI repression at Pine Ridge remained intense through 1976. Meanwhile, the anti-rape movement had made significant progress as part of the larger women's movement, and prison reform was still a serious topic. The Symbionese Liberation Army (SLA), who like some early radical criminologists romanticized prisoners, stormed onto the scene and kidnapped Patricia Hearst from a home near the journal's Berkeley office. It was not long before SLA members were incinerated on real-time TV. This episode helped to undermine much of the remaining public support the prisoner movement enjoyed and reinvigorated right-wing countersubversive forces that had run perilously short of genuine Communists to persecute. They seized upon the "international terrorism" issue by making spurious links between the SLA, the Weather Underground, Germany's Baader-Meinhof group, the Italian Red Brigades, the Angry Brigade (a British terrorist group founded on the principles of the Enrages of 1968 France), and the PLO, even though from 1965 to 1976 a substantial number of incidents involving political violence were attributable to right-wing and racist sources. The grand jury had become a police state instrument during its heyday between 1970 and 1974. Domestic government spying was intense; Francis Ford Coppola's movie, The Conversation, dramatized the Watergate-era paranoia over wiretapping, invasion of privacy, and the apparent absence of conscience at the highest levels of government. Between 1957 and 1974, the FBI's COINTELPRO operation kept files on nearly 500,000 Americans whom J. Edgar Hoover and other FBI officials considered to be subversives or potential "national security risks" and infiltrated organizations such as the Medical Committee for Human Rights and the National Lawyers Guild, not to mention the Black Panther Party and the American Indian Movement. Federal intervention in the 1970s transformed U.S. law enforcement into the largest, most expensive, and most punitive system of justice in the world. A "police-industrial complex" was created through enormous subsidies and an integration of military expertise, command and control techniques, and weapons, communications, and data collection technology. By 1974, the police received nearly 60% of the nation's $15 billion criminal justice budget - eight times the amount allocated a decade earlier. The number of police officers in this country nearly doubled in the decade between 1965 and 1975. Police helicopters hovered over barrios and housing projects; paramilitary SWAT units learned team policing concepts that adapted Vietnam-era armed responses. African American, Latino, and left organizations opposed these trends and called for civilian review boards and "community control," but to little avail. In the end, the U.S. became even more insecure about crime and was readied for the prison explosion of the 1980s and 1990s. Articles of impeachment were drafted against President ("Tricky Dick") Nixon in 1974 during the political and constitutional crisis known as the Watergate scandal. Having lost the confidence of U.S. ruling circles, Nixon was forced from office. In Vietnam, fighting escalated and the United States would soon be forced to exit in disarray. Rightist dictatorships collapsed in Portugal (1974), Greece (1974), and Spain (with Franco's death in 1975). With this came the precondition for united European democracies to coalesce into a future economic superpower, but it also unleashed liberation movements in Africa as Portugal undertook immediate decolonization. In France and Italy, the balance of forces had swung substantially to the left. The end of the great postwar economic boom of 1945 to 1973 was punctuated by the OPEC oil price hike. A world economic recession ensued. The 1974 recession under President Ford was perhaps the deepest cyclical downturn since the 1930s and was exacerbated by a military slowdown under conditions of deescalation and detente that deprived the U.S. economy of a defense against recession that had been relied upon in the 1960s. Globalization had entered a new monetary and financial regime in response to "stagflation" - low growth due to an absence of profitable investments, low productivity, and rising prices. Japan's economy showed zero growth from 1974 to 1975 and state managers in Europe's industrial powers were overwhelmed by high unemployment and the ineffectiveness of traditional Keynesian remedies. Corporate power had attained a global reach, first as multinationals and then as transnationals, and in 1973 the corporate-political elite created a corresponding policy-making institution, the Trilateral Commission, with the "ungovernability of democracies" high on the agenda. Within such an ambiance, a progressive criminology movement emerged primarily at U.C. Berkeley's School of Criminology to challenge the traditional guardians of order and to begin the work of transforming the self-crippled discourse of technicians (to use Alvin Gouldner's phrase). With its commitment to combining radical analysis with political organizing, it is perhaps miraculous that the enterprise survived at all in what is probably the most reactionary field in the social sciences. The progressive criminology movement was international in scope: it was not confined to one national culture, but varied in its cultural and political origins. It was conditioned by the events of 1968 - the French May, the Italian "Hot Autumn," the German 68er "cultural revolution" and student movement, and the year of the barricade in the U.S., in short, the worldwide student rebellion together with the My Lai massacre and Tet Offensive in Vietnam, the Soviet occupation of Czechoslovakia, and Martin Luther King's assassination. In 1968, the School of Criminology at Berkeley had a radical presence that actively promoted student power, antiwar and anti-imperialist politics, and was close to the Black Panthers in Oakland. We were active in the campus-wide strike led by the Third World Liberation Front in 1969, the massive community and student struggle known as "People's Park," the struggle against the use of behavioral modification and brain surgery in prison, as well as the campaign for community control of the police in 1971. The Bay Area Women Against Rape came into existence in 1971. In the summer of 1972, the Union of Radical Criminologists (URC) was formed by a small group of students and teachers at the Berkeley School of Criminology with the aim of becoming a national organization, promoting radical ideas and community projects, as well as supporting the victims of academic repression. The URC was not long lasting, but it served as an important transitional organization. It had a hand in the anthology, Policing America, edited by Tony Platt and Lynn Cooper. In 1973, the URC and NACLA jointly initiated the Center for Research on Criminal Justice. Its research on repression and national trends conducted for the purpose of serving organizations struggling against the criminal justice system - culminated in the 1975 classic, The Iron Fist and the Velvet Glove: An Analysis of the U.S. Police. Crime and Social Justice began as a task group within URC and commenced publication in 1974. Its founders saw the need for a publication that would "bring together the analyses and programs of people working to build a movement to overcome the oppressive criminal justice system and the system of exploitation it supports." A global perspective was built into the initial issues because we saw that the U.S. government was involved in developing and legitimizing repressive criminal justice systems around the world. Indeed, to reduce criminology to domestic issues was to unnecessarily restrict our understanding of repression and resistance. The journal has endured, independent of institutional support, under various titles ever since. Some publishing know-how carried over from staff members who had also worked on Issues in Criminology (1965 to 1975), a publication of the graduate students at Berkeley's School of Criminology that was an outgrowth of the Free Speech Movement. The editorial mandate of Social Justice has expanded over the years beyond issues of crime, punishment, and social control to encompass globalism, international human rights and civil rights domestically, border and immigration issues, environmental victims and health and safety issues, critiques of the state and welfare reform strategies, as well as analyses of gender-and ethnicity-based inequalities. The journal remains true to its initial task of debunking and transforming agency-determined criminal justice research, but it has also incorporated elements of world-systems analysis, which took shape in the 1970s as a form of critique capable of explaining America's imperial role in the global system known as historical capitalism. Articulate world-systems theorists, Immanuel Wallerstein and Chris Chase-Dunn, belong to our advisory board, and Andre Gunder Frank remains a valued contributor and at-large adviser. Incorporation of the worldsystems perspective preceded, but was also reinforced by, the 1988 merger of Crime and Social Justice and Contemporary Marxism (1980 to 1987). Many on the latter staff had been members of NACLA's West Coast office, which accounts for much of the rich "Americanist" perspective that would appear in the pages of Social Justice. Before the merger, the two journals were projects of Global Options, a nonprofit institute in San Francisco committed to research and advocacy on world affairs that was founded in 1986. Uncommon Wealth: The Contribution of Great Britain, Canada, and Australia European critical criminologists established the largely academic, left-ofcenter European Society for the Study of Deviance and Social Control, whose first conference was organized by Mario Simondi, Stan Cohen, Ian Taylor, and Karl Schumann in September 1973. Members of the Crime and Social Justice Collective participated. The British component emerged in 1968 - a year of student occupations in Britain, the emergence of Tariq Ali as a student leader, an antiVietnam demonstration in London that turned into a battle with police outside the U.S. embassy, and Enoch Powell's prediction of "rivers of blood" in an impending race war - from a group consisting of left activists Laurie Taylor, Stan Cohen, Mary McIntosh, Ian Taylor, Paul Walton, and Jock Young. In 1973, the latter three, who became Contributing Editors to our journal, published The New Criminology. This influential work was an ironically titled critique, as it was a return to European grand sociological theory, although some at the time would have preferred its focus to be beyond criminology. A collective work, it had its origins in the National Deviancy Conference, which was formed by the 1968 group and grew to some 400 members who shared a dissatisfaction with European social democracy and a desire to expose the criminogenic nature of British capitalism. This United Kingdom-based body of sociologists and individuals involved in social action (on behalf of squatters, radical social workers, and the prisoners' union) did its best to support the group of radicals under attack at Berkeley's School of Criminology. Many of the original participants are still active, along with newer faces.2 From this group and others working along similar lines flowed a rich literature, ranging from those of Stuart Hall and his associate's work at the Birmingham Center for Contemporary Cultural Studies to "realist" criminology, social control theory generally, and variants on postmodern theory. Hall, long one of our Contributing Editors, was a major figure in the revival of the British Left in the 1960s and 1970s and remains a visionary race theorist in the 1990s. The work of this British group resonated with that being done in the U.S. since the U.K. also experienced a massive shift to coercion in the 1970s, with the "birth of the `law and order' society," as Stuart Hall, Charles Critcher, Tony Jefferson, John Clarke, and Brian Roberts argued in Policing the Crisis: Mugging, the State, and Law and Order. The Labour government then in power presided over a deteriorating economy, an annual inflation rate above 25%, unrest in Northern Ireland, countercultural drug use, squatters, nonwhite immigration, and a general "crisis of hegemony." The term "mugging" was imported from the U.S. in the 1972 to 1973 period into British culture as an image and set of relationships already condensed in U.S. law enforcement ideology - crime, black youth, fear of social disorder, and the conviction that society had become too permissive toward crime and criminals. Policing the Crisis made good use of Marxist cultural theory inflected through Gramsci's theory of hegemony and an Althusserian conception of the media as an ideological state apparatus largely concerned with the reproduction of dominant ideologies. Another important theorist, Paul Gilroy, also discussed the evolution of "race" as a policing problem and the transformation of urban disturbances in the 1970s into a race problem. Tony Bunyan made a significant contribution with his The Political Police in Britain, through his work on the now-defunct State Research, and through police monitoring units, including that of the Greater London Council. Another critical approach came from Christopher Williams, whose Environmental Victims (Vol. 23, No. 4) we published in 1996. Currently, despite Prime Minister Tony Blair's tough-on-crime stance, the British are even less secure in terms of environmental and criminal victimization, and in terms of the workplace. The Canadian movement, which was strongly influenced culturally and politically by Europe and the U.S., began to congeal in 1975. Marie-Andr6e Bertrand was a Contributing Editor to our journal at the time its first issue appeared. She had experienced the wave of neoconservatism that engulfed the Universite de Montreal in reaction to the 1968 uprisings before coming to Berkeley asa visiting professor in 1973. 'Another early participant, Yvon Dandurand, noted in 1975 that attempts to create a radical criminology periodical had failed and that radical approaches to criminology appeared in the community at large and in struggles for social justice (such as Claire Culhane's work with the Prisoners' Rights Group, First Nations struggles, and those concerned with police surveillance), rather than in academia. Over 10 years later, when we published Canada and the U.S: Criminal Justice Connections (CSJ No. 26, edited by R.S. Ratner), Canada still lacked a radical criminology journal. That changed with the inauguration of the Journal of Human Justice (1989-1995), spearheaded by Chuck Reasons, Tulio Caputo, Brian MacLean, R.S. Ratner, Paul Havemann, and others. (In 1996, that title continued as Critical Criminology: An International Journal, a publication of the Critical Criminology Division of the American Society of Criminology.) In 1974, the Bathurst riot occurred in Australia, destroying the prison and leading to aperiod of reform in the prison system. Gang violence and street assaults were media and popular concerns in the mid-1960s and early 1970s, a decade of relative affluence. Mass Vietnam protests, opposition to the 1972 South African rugby tour, and the rise of Koori (aboriginal) protest and militancy generated a physical contest over public space, the streets, and a volatile ideological climate into which issues of crime, especially "street crime," were inserted. In this climate, the Alternative Criminology Journal (1975 to 1981), edited by David Brown, sought to radicalize criminology by ending its separation as a separate discipline, divorced from political theory and political economy. Writing in Law in Context: A Socio-Legal Journal (Pat O'Malley and Kit Carsen served on it Editorial Board), Adrian Howe argued, as had Elliott Currie in 1974, that the point, however, was to get out of criminology and to reconceptualize the whole terrain as a sociology of law, crime, and criminalization. Although Australia had been incorporated as a new subsystem in the world-system through the "Pacific Rim Strategy," it has resisted some of the more punitive responses to a law and order culture, such as "three strikes" legislation and the death penalty, which American crime policy embodies. Some of this resistance comes to Australia via Europe. In an "Australian response" to the theme of "Law and Order for Progressives?" in our journal, Gill Boehringer, Dave Brown, Brendan Edgeworth, Russell Hogg, and Ian Ramsay argued in favor of broadening the debate over crime to include domestic violence, health and safety, and the practices and control of state agencies such as the police. Later, Pat O'Malley guest edited an issue of Social Justice entitled The Politics of Empowerment in Australia (Vol. 16, No. 3, 1989) that fulfills that objective while exploring Australia's role in the global system. Italian Critical Currents Events in Italy during our founding years paralleled many experienced in the U.S., with several major exceptions. One was the amazing sea of red banners during huge mobilizations of the Italian Communist Party, the labor movement, and an insurgent extra-parliamentary Left I had witnessed during Italy's "Hot Autumn" in 1969. Such wide-scale support for the "Italian Road to Socialism" equally impressed members of Crime and Social Justice Collective who attended the European Society for the Study of Deviance and Social Control in Florence in 1973. Public confidence in the government had plummeted and, by 1974, Italy briefly lacked a government altogether. The Red Brigades emerged in the early 1970s, a time of worsening economic problems and great political turbulence, with saber-rattling on the Right, kidnappings, bombings of major Italian cities, and selective shootings, especially of law enforcement officers. The CIA poured in millions of dollars to prevent the Communists from coming to power (also a goal of the Red Brigades) and trained the Italian security services to confront disorders and student demonstrations, to prepare dossiers, and make use of bank data and the tax returns of individual citizens. An aggressive Italian judiciary and law-enforcement apparatus made innovative use of repentant and confessed criminals turned state's witnesses, first to quell the Red Brigades and then to take on the Mafia. There was some exchange between the extra-parliamentary opposition (Lotta Continua, Il Manifesto, and Potere Operaio) and intellectual circles and the student movement. Lotta Continua was active in the prisoners' movement. At the time, prisons were at the boiling point in Britain, the U.S., Australia, Canada, and Italy. Not surprisingly, Dario Melossi and Massimo Pavarini focused their work on the origins of the penitentiary system. Their The Prison and the Factory builds on Marx' concept of primitive accumulation. They reintroduced Georg Rusche and Otto Kirchheimer's Punishment and Social Structure and later offered a critique of Michel Foucault's Discipline and Punishment, which was influenced, like many of the works developed in that milieu, by the theoretical work of Antonio Gramsci and Louis Althusser. Melossi was a kindred spirit to our journal group and we had the pleasure of meeting him during his brief research sojourn in Berkeley. He was a founder and member of the Bologna School, which was responsible for the publication of La Questione Criminale: Rivista di Ricerca e Dibattito su Devianza e Controllo Sociale up to the 1980s and of Dei Delitti e delle Pene in the 1990s. Alessandro Baratta and Massimo Pavarini recently resuscitated Dei Delitti e delle Pene (under the auspices of the Italian National Research Council) after a three-year hiatus, with the aim of interpreting the changes in crime and the social order within the processes of European integration and economic globalization, of analyzing discourses on crime and punishment, and of theorizing on issues such as the needs for safety and its relation to constitutional and human rights. Others from the early period, including Tamar Pitch, Vincenzo Ruggiero, and others, still work together through that journal. In 1989, members of the Social Justice Editorial Board would work with the International League for the Rights and Liberation of Peoples to compile an issue entitled Human Rights and People's Rights: Views from North and South. The League was founded in 1976 by an Italian member of Parliament, Lelio Basso, who before his death in 1978 made clear his belief that socialism without democracy was not possible, just as a democratic order without activism was not possible. We knew of Basso's work in the early 1970s, when he presented a paper in Santiago, Chile, on the use of legality in the phase of transition to socialism, as well as that of Giovanni Arrighi, who has made an important contribution to the world-systems literature. The Critical Legacy in Germany In the Federal Republic of Germany, the SDS (Sozialistischer Deutscher Studentenbund) became the core of a widespread student rebellion against reactionary regimes in the Third World, against U.S. policy in Vietnam, and against long-standing government attempts to supplement the constitution with emergency laws that would confer dictatorial powers on the government in the event of a political crisis at home or abroad. In 1968, the Young Socialists - the organization of the younger members of the Social Democratic Party - declared its opposition to the emergency legislation; the student rebellion, increasingly under the banner of revolutionary socialist slogans, also called for its immediate rejection. In April 1968, after a right-wing attempt to assassinate SDS leader Rudi Dutschke (following incitements especially in the reactionary Springer Press), riots erupted. Berlin and other cities in West Germany saw the heaviest street fighting since the Weimar Republic, and students and young workers throughout West Germany invaded Springer's offices and burned its vans in protest. In a major setback for the student movement, the government passed the emergency legislation with only minor modifications. The over-escalation of radical direct action tendencies that followed soon destroyed the SDS and led to the disintegration of the nascent alliance between core groups in the working-class trade union movement and the intellectual opposition. This was the Germany I encountered in the summer of 1969, when I was working in Libri Buchhandlung's Frankfurt warehouse and studying sociology part time at the University of Mainz. An older factory worker who had quit the Communist Party in disgust over Stalin's policies tutored me in "scientific socialism" to offset my fascination with the ideas of the French Situationist International ("All power to the imagination!"). It was not until I returned to the U.S. that I became familiar with German critical criminology.3 Much of that early work hadbeen organized under the banner of the Arbeitskreis Junger Kriminologen (Working Party of Young Criminologists). They began publishing Kriminologisches Journal in 1969 and the journal continues to be associated with the University of Hamburg. Fritz Sack, a central figure, was a visiting professor at the University of California, Berkeley, in the mid-I960s and has been a contributor to Social Justice. Another journal, Kritische Justiz, launched in 1968, survives today with an editorial mandate to analyze the law and its practical application in its social, economic, and political contexts. Similar to other countries, there was serious contention over whether the new criminology should be critical, radical, or Marxist. An article by Falco Werkentin, Michael Hofferbert, and Michael Bauman that appeared in our second issue is entitled "Criminology as Police Science or `How Old Is the New Criminology?"' (CSJ No. 2, 1974). It reflects a Marxist perspective that distinguished itself from an early critical approach of Fritz Sack, a "Marxist-interactionist theory of criminology." Helmut Janssen, an editor of Radikale Kriminologie, an anthology of primarily U.S.-based radical criminologists published in German in 1988, claimed that a radical or Marxist criminology was never able to develop in the Federal Republic of Germany because of the prohibition on the German Communist Party (KPD), the Berufsverbot-a purge mandated by the Right of the professions, including the civil service and education - the fragmentation of the Left, and the absence of a university-level Marxist school. Yet critical criminology has deep roots in the "critical" social theory of the Frankfurt Institute of Social Research (the "Frankfurt School"). Theorists like Max Horkheimer, Theodor Adorno, and Herbert Marcuse (a group forced into exile in 1933 and then only reluctantly readmitted in 1945) generated powerful critiques of structures of inequality, authority, and power, as well as of ideological hegemony. Important for the 1968 movement were theories drawing on the Frankfurt School, among others, that argued that the working classes of the West had lost their revolutionary vocation, and that the focus of such activity had shifted to the peoples of the Third World and to marginalized sectors in the West, including immigrants, women, and youth. The Frankfurt School also accomplished what Foucault's panopticon theory of social control did not: it linked the concept of discipline (and what this means culturally) with changes in the capitalist management of work. Georg Rusche and Otto Kirchheimer's Punishment and Social Structure, which was introduced by Horkheimer and ironically only appeared in German translation in 1974, is a product of the Frankfurt School and was repopularized during the crisis of the late 1960s and early 1970s after years of neglect. The School has had other lasting impacts. Sebastian Scheerer and Henner Hess, in their recent defense and reformulation of the social control thesis against the steady encroachment of the concepts of "discipline" and "social exclusion" draw on Marcuse's One Dimensional Man to link his notion of "repressive tolerance," the harmless and sometimes illusionary satisfaction of real or artificially induced needs, with social control. After the events of 1989 (e.g., the collapse of the GDR), Jirgen Habermas (once Adorno's assistant) cautioned the state-supporting legal establishment that a constitutional state cannot be maintained without a radical democracy. Another aspect of Germany's new criminology is Falco Werkentin's work with the Berlin-based Biirgerrechte and Polizei (Civil Rights and the Police, CILIP). Since the mid-1970s, he has produced diverse research projects and publications on German police history and on the politics of internal security. As the anti-authoritarian revolts of the 1960s peaked, sectors of the German New Left devolved into a wave of bombings, kidnappings, and murders by groups such as the Baader-Meinhof/Red Army Faction. Beginning in the 1970s, this triggered an unprecedented enlargement and reconstruction of police and secret services in the Federal Republic. No federal police force like the FBI existed in Germany before the Red Army Faction terrorist campaign of the 1970s. To allay fears that another Hitler might arise, West Germany's post-World War II constitution had established a very loose confederation of states (Lander), each with its own police. The terrorist threat was a pretext for the Lander to cede some of their power and strengthen the federal border police (BKA) into an FBI-like institution. After unification with East Germany, the basis for expansion of police power shifted from the terrorism of the 1970s to the dangers of atomic technology and the destruction of the environment to the drug trade and right-wing extremism. In 1986, I returned to Frankfurt to participate in a symposium organized by Heinz Dieterich on "State Terrorism in the Third World." Papers by Noam Chomsky and James Petras (both members of our Editorial Advisory Board) as well as by Edward S. Herman were eventually published in our special issue, Contragate and Counterterrorism: A Global Perspective (CSJ 27-28, 1987). I reconnected with Falco Werkentin in Berlin as well as with the delightful editor of Das Argument, Wolfgang F. Haug, at the Freie Universitat Berlin. I was also fortunate to meet world-systems theorists at the Starnberg Institute for Research on Global Structures, Developments, and Crises. Folker Frobel, Jorgen Heinrichs, and Otto Kreye had just published Umbruch in der Weltwirtschaft (which can be translated as reorganization of or revolutionary change in the world economy), an exploration into the new international division of labor and the crisis of the capitalist world system. That April of 1986 truly felt like a crisis, if only because radioactive fallout from the Chernobyl disaster was raining down on Germany, on me, and, by coincidence, on Pat O'Malley, the Australian theorist. In 1974, the architect of Ostpolitik, the Social Democrat Willy Brandt, had been forced to resign because of a spy scandal involving East Germany and was succeeded by Helmut Schmidt. That year, rapid inflation was accompanied by rising unemployment and was exacerbated by the presence of four million guest workers and their families. The crisis passed, but a more revolutionary event would later envelop the East. Just months beforluence, though, was a brief interlude in which some policies of the former Soviet Union were at times uncritically accepted. 7. The Critical Criminology Division has 320 members (under 190 faculty members and under 90 students and other researchers), although I have also seen a total figure of over 400. Both the Marxist section and the Political Economy of the World-System (PEWS) section of the American Sociological Association struggle each year to reach 400 members. GREGoRY SHANK is the Managing Editor of Social Justice (GregoryS9 @aol.com). He was a member of the original Crime and Social Justice Collective. Shank describes what was happening in 1974 in terms of the political-economic conditions and social movements that propelled the unlikely emergence of a radical criminology around the world. Copyright Social Justice Summer 1999 Quellen:UMI SOCIAL JUSTICE 07/1999 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 22Jun1999 USA: Latin America and the World Economy Since 1800.(Review). By Engerman, Stanley L. Edited by John H. Coatsworth and Alan M. Taylor. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1998. xiv + 484 pp. Tables, notes, references, and index. Cloth, $49.95. ISBN 0674512804; paper, $24.95. ISBN 0674512812. Reviewed by Stanley L. Engerman This collection of 15 papers on the last two centuries of Latin American history is based upon two conferences held in southern Europe, with the editors and publishers being from the United States. And while the majority of authors are also from the United States, there are several from Latin America and from Europe. Most are young scholars, several of the essays being based on dissertations still in progress, and others being extensions of recently completed doctoral work. The volume is interdisciplinary in its authorship, although there are more economists than historians. This is not surprising given the volume's purpose as described by the editors. According to Coatsworth and Taylor, a primary goal of the book was to illustrate the applications of neoclassical economic theory and quantitative methods to the study of Latin American economic history, and to demonstrate the value of such techniques in explaining the relative backwardness (compared to the United States) of the Latin American economies. To use these techniques, as they indicate, does not necessarily mean that the only acceptable answers are economic. Bather, the data and economic analysis are used to determine which non-economic factors might prove to be important in explaining the past. The essays do draw heavily upon economic analysis and quantitative methods (there are 85 tables and 26 figures), as well as the frequent usage of regression analysis and total factor productivity measurement. The volume is quite successful in applying its methods to questions long central to Latin American history, such as the causes of relative backwardness, the role of financial institutions, the impact of various legal changes, and tariff policy. It also makes important contributions to these debates, even with only limited footnotes to such earlier stalwarts as Andre Gunder Frank, Celso Furtado, and Raul Prebisch, and with barely a full comment on dependency theory. The geographic coverage is also rather traditional, with Brazil, Argentina, and Mexico being the most studied nations, by articles if not by pages (articles varying in length from 16 to 48 pages). Coatsworth and Taylor provide a broad definition of the "new economic history," including its early stage with reliance on economic theory, the application of quantitative methods, and the collection of primary data from archives. Also included are essays reflecting more recent developments, such as the study of institutions and welfare aspects of growth, as well as of individual businesses and the link between economic history and business history. The book is divided into five sections that reflect the main topics of the "new economic history": International Comparisons, Patterns of Investment and Growth, Measuring National and International Integration, Institutions and Economic Growth, and Government Policies and the External Sector. The first set of essays takes up comparisons between Latin America and other countries, as well as between nations within Latin America. The first essay, by John H. Coatsworth, compares the GDP per capita in the U.S. from 1700 to 1994 with that of other countries. His estimates indicate that Latin America's relative decline set in between 1700 and 1800, and that the twentieth century saw some closing of the gap. He briefly examines the roles of factor endowments, trade, and taxes in these patterns. Lee J. Alston, Gary D. Libecap, and Bernardo Mueller contrast land policy in the United States in the nineteenth century with that in contemporary Brazil, arguing that the ability to enforce property rights was central to the greater United States economic success. Andre A. Hofman and Nanno Mulder's comparison of productivity performance between 1950 and 1994 in Brazil and Mexico indicates that increased capital stock was important in accounting for growth in both countries. However, the largest sectoral differences between the Latin American nations and the United States in value-added per hour worked were in agriculture, due to differences in capital intensity, and in the level of output per unit of input. In a study of the Sao Paulo Bolsa between 1876 and 1917, Anne Hanley argues for the overall importance of domestic capital formation, showing that foreign capital was important only in a few sectors. Gerardo della Paolera and Taylor claim that the financial structure of interwar Argentina was poor, with domestic banks weaker than foreign banks. Michael J. Twomey's study of foreign investment in Latin America in the twentieth century points out, not unexpectedly, the importance of railroads and infrastructure as well as high capital inflow levels in the first part of the century. The studies of market integration include regional incomes in Argentina, money markets in Brazil, and Argentine financial markets. Carlos Newland, using various proxies, indicates some of the differences between the Littoral and the Interior in Argentina between 1810 and 1870. Gail D. Triner, on the basis of considerable primary data collected for Brazilian banks between 1889 and 1930, shows that there was some convergence in money markets that helped contribute to economic development. And Leonard I. Nakamura and Carlos E. J. M. Zarazaga, on the basis of estimates of returns on stocks and bonds in Argentina between 1900 and 1930, demonstrate a similarity in returns compared to those in the United States and the United Kingdom, suggesting there was a world-wide capital market at that time. The institutions analysed in relation to economic growth include laws respecting incorporation and the contracts between sugar mills and colonos in Cuba. Stephen Haber uses primary sources relating to cotton textile manufacturing in Brazil to assess the impact of the legal changes that took place around 1890 regarding limited liability and mandatory disclosure for corporations. Haber argues these changes led to an increased growth in the industry, with the new firms having higher productivity than those formed earlier. Alan Dye analyzes cane grower contracts in Cuba for the first four decades after the end of slavery and claims that these contracts were less coercive and exploitative than had been earlier assumed on the basis of considerably less evidence. The essay by Aurora Gomez-Galvarriato provides new data on real wages in Mexico between 1900 and 1920. Gomez-Galvarriato's figures reveal that this was probably a period of declining standard of living, at least for those workers at the cotton textile mill that provided the wage data. The last section includes a concise summary of William R. Summerhill's work on various aspects of Brazilian railroads between 1854 and 1889. Summerhill estimates a benefit of this innovation higher than for any of the developed nations, but comparable to that for Mexico. Graciela Marquez's detailed measurement and description of Mexican tariffs during the period of manufacturing expansion from 1892 to 1909 argues that growth occurred in a period of falling tariffs, but not because the government lowered tariff rates. Rather, the decline was the result of a combination of unchanged specific tariffs and rising world prices. The final essay, by Daniel Diaz Fuentes, is concerned with interwar monetary issues for Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico, examining their varying successes in returning to the gold standard, as well as their differences in meeting external financial obligations. In describing these differences in policy as well as in the timing of introducing central banks, he claims that the influence of the so-called "money doctors" has been greatly exaggerated. The essays in Latin America and the World Economy Since 1800 are generally of high quality, with a very useful blend of historical and economic concerns. They deal with important issues and their explanations of both the positive economic growth of these nations and the changing relative backwardness compared to the United States are worth further study. The book will be useful reading for all interested in the economic history of Latin America. Stanley L. Engerman is John H. Munro professor of economics and professor of history at the University of Rochester. He is currently working with Stephen Haber and Kenneth Sokoloff on a project dealing with the economic growth of North and South America. Business History Review, Vol.73, No.2 COPYRIGHT 1999 President and Fellows of Harvard College. (c) 1999 Information Access Company. All rights reserved. This article may only be stored on a computer network for a maximum of 30 days. Quellen:IAC TRADE AND INDUSTRY DATABASE BUSINESS HISTORY REVIEW 22/06/1999 P341 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 01Mai1999 USA: An indigenous view of the New World Order.(a book's portrayal of Somalia) - Part 2 of 2. By Lauderdale, Pat and Toggia, Pietro. Doornbus, Martin 1993 "Pasture and Polis: The Roots of Political Marginalization of Somali Pastoralism." In Conflict and the Decline of Pastoralism in the Horn of Africa, edited by John Markakis. London: Macmillan Press. Fitzpatrick, Peter 1992 The Mythology of Modern Law. London: Routledge. Foucault, Michel 1984 "What is Enlightenment?" Pp. 32-49 in The Foucault Reader, edited by P. Rabinow. New York: Pantheon. 1988 Politics, Philosophy, Culture. New York: Routledge. Frank, Andre Gunder 1998 ReOrient. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. French, James Strange 1836 Elkswatawa: or, The Prophet of the West. New York: Harper and Brothers. Gills, Barry and Andre Gunder Frank 1992 "World System Cycles, Crises, and Hegemonial Shifts, 1700 B.C. to 1700 A.D." Review 15: 621-687. Gills, Barry and Joel Rocamora 1992 "Low Intensity Democracy." Third World Quarterly 13:501-523. Goldberg, David T. 1993 Racist Culture. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell. Gurr, Ted Robert 1994 "Peoples Against States: Ethnopolitical Conflict and the Changing World System." International Studies Quarterly 38: 347-377. Harvey, David 1989 The Condition of Postmodernity. Cambridge: Blackwell. Hollinger, Robert 1994 Postmodernism and the Social Sciences. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Hunt, Michael 1987 Ideology and U.S. Foreign Policy. New Haven: Yale University Press. Inverarity, James, Pat Lauderdale and Barry Feld 1983 Law and Society. Boston, MA: Little, Brown. Josephy, Alvin M. Jr. 1984 Now That The Buffalo's Gone. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press. Kinietz, W. Vernon 1965 The Indians of the Western Great Lakes, 1615-1760. Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press. Krasner, Stephen 1994 "International Political Economy: Abiding Discord." Review of International Political Economy 1: 13-19. 1985 Structural Conflict: The Third Worm Against Global Liberalism. Berkeley: University of California Press. Lauderdale, Pat 1997 "Indigenous North American Jurisprudence." International Journal of Comparative Sociology 38:131-148. 1994 "Indigenous North American Alternatives to Modern Law and Punishment: Lessons of Nature." Pages 133-156 in Herren-los: Herrschaft, Erkenntnis, und Lebensform, edited by Claudia von Werlhof, Anne Schweighofer and Werner Ernst. Paris: Peter Lang. Lauderdale, Pat and Randall Amster (eds.) 1997 Lives in the Balance: Perspectives on Global Injustice and Inequality. Leiden: The Netherlands: Brill. Lauderdale, Pat and Michael Cruit 1993 The Struggle for Control: A Study of Law, Disputes and Deviance. New York: SUNY Press. Lefebvre, Jeffrey 1991 Arms for the Horn. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. Lewis, I.M. 1998 "Doing Violence to Ethnography: A Response to Catherine Besteman's 'Representing Violence and Othering." Cultural Anthropology 13: 100-109. Maine, Henry Sumner 1909 Ancient Law: Its Connection with the Early History of Society and its Relation to Modern Ideas. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul Ltd. Makinda, Samuel 1992 "Somalia." In Security in the Horn of Africa. Adelphi Paper, No. 269. London: The International Institute for Strategic Studies. 1993 Seeking Peace from Chaos. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. Maxted, Julia and Abebe Zegeye 1997 "State Disintegration and Human Rights in Africa." International Journal of Comparative Sociology 38: 64-86. Nagel, Joane 1997 American Indian Ethnic Renewal. New York: Oxford University Press. O'Donnell, Guillermo 1987 "Forms of State and Socio-economic Change." Pages 200-219 in The Political Economy of Law, edited by Yash Ghai et al. Delhi: Oxford University Press. Oliverio, Annamarie 1998 The State of Terror. New York: SUNY Press. Oliverio, Annamarie and Pat Lauderdale 1990 "Indigenous Jurisprudence." Pp. 59-78 in The Implementation of Equal Rights for Men and Women, edited by Fanny Tabak. Onati: The Onati International Institute for the Sociology of Law. Pearce, Roy Harvey 1953 The Savages of America: A Study of the Indian and the Idea of Civilization. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins Press. Perelman, Michael 1983 Classical Political Economy: Primitive Accumulation and the Social Division of Labor. Totowa, NJ: Rowman and Allanheld. Rodney, Walter 1982 How Europe Underdeveloped Africa. Washington, D.C.: Howard University Press. Samatar, Abdi Ismail 1992 "Destruction of State and Society in Somalia: Beyond the Tribal Convention." The Journal of Modern African Studies 30: 625-641. 1989 The State and Rural Transformation in Northern Somalia, 1884-86. Madison, WI: The University of Wisconsin Press. Samatar, Said 1991 Somalia: A Nation in Turmoil. London: A Minority Rights Group Report. Samatar, Said and Leitin, David 1987 Somalia: Nation in Search of a State. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. Seidman, Robert 1987 "Contract Law, the Free Market and State Intervention." In The Political Economy of Law, edited by Ghai, Yash et al. Delhi: Oxford University Press. Smyth, Frank and Stephen Goose 1994 "Arming Genocide in Rwanda." Foreign Affairs 73: 86-96. Tar, Zoltan 1977 The Frankfurt School. New York: John Wiley. Thomas, George et al. (eds.) 1987 Institutional Analysis: Studies of State, Society, and the Individual. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Thompson, E. P. 1987 "Capitalism and the Rule of Law." In The Political Economy of Law, edited by Ghai et al. Delhi: Oxford University Press. Thornton, Russell 1987 American Indian Holocaust and Survival. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press. von Werlhof, Claudia 1991 Was haben die Huhner mit dem Dollar zu tun? Munich: Verlag Frauenoffensive. Wallerstein, Immanuel 1986 Africa and the Modern World. Trenton, NJ: Africa World Press. Wolde-Mariam, Mesfin 1977 Somalia: The Problem Child of Africa. Addis Ababa: Artistic Printing Press. Woodward, Peter 1996 The Horn of Africa: State Politics and International Relations. New York: Martin's Press. Journal of Asian and African Studies, Vol.34, No.2 COPYRIGHT 1999 E.J. Brill (The Netherlands). (c) 1999 Information Access Company. All rights reserved. This article may only be stored on a computer network for a maximum of 30 days. Quellen:IAC TRADE AND INDUSTRY DATABASE JOURNAL OF ASIAN & AFRICAN STUDIES 01/05/1999 P157 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 01Mai1999 USA: An indigenous view of the New World Order.(a book's portrayal of Somalia) - Part 1 of 2. By Lauderdale, Pat and Toggia, Pietro. Introduction In the "New World Order" Somalia is characterized as a deviant society, especially by Western countries. This characterization is magnified by focusing upon armed conflicts among different groups in Somalia and is marked by a neglect of global forces and history, including indigenous perspectives. The benchmark for judging the nature and scale of the crisis in Somalia is the condition of statelessness, measured by the absence of a central political authority and the modern claim to an ostensible universal rule of law. The creation and efficient operation of a central state is considered a universal measuring scale for stability, a yardstick employed by the New World Order (cf. Gills and Rocamora, 1992; Hollinger, 1994). The New World Order can be traced to the breakup of the bipolar configuration of power some twenty years ago, and the Gulf "War" was touted as an implementation of that Order. The early 1990s often are viewed as the watershed for the emergence of the New World Order, especially the rhetoric of the Gulf "War." The Order is characterized by global hegemony, the increasing role of the United Nations in advancing foreign policy, military interventions under the guise of peacekeeping, and the acceleration of a market economy ostensibly directed by global forces such as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund. The global hegemony touts Western values and typically suggests that the world today is faced with a choice between homogenous globalization (vulgarized as McWorld) and secessionist self-determination (vulgarized as Jihad), despite the enormous complexity belying this false dichotomy (Lauderdale and Amster, 1997; Frank, 1998). Since its independence in 1960, Somalia also has been identified as a deviant society by countries throughout Africa. This negative dismissal, in part, stems from its defiance of The Organization for African Unity (OAU) charter that sanctifies the existing borders of African countries. In the recent past, Somalia's nation state also has made territorial claims over all the neighboring territories inhabited by the Somali people, notably, against Ethiopia, Kenya and Djibouti. Ethiopian scholars such as Wolde-Mariam (1977) portray Somalia as deviant even in their book titles, e.g., Somalia: A Problem Child of Africa (following the war with Ethiopia in the Ogaden region). Somalia is not only defined as deviant but also its people are depicted as incapable of solving their own problems. The people are identified with the "old" world - the world of tribalism and clans, disorder and continual conflict - rather than the new world - the world of radical and atomistic individualism, and the modern state, ordered through the rule of law and conflict resolution (cf. Lauderdale and Amster, 1997). External intervention into a country such as Somalia is legitimated in part by such discourse, for example, by the United States officially sanctioned via the United Nations. While this intervention has enabled relief food for the hungry to be delivered in the short run, it also has expanded the pervasive image of Somalia as a barbarian nation and led to long term problems that have exacerbated human survival, freedom, and self-determination. As Abdi Samatar notes: The logic of the traditionalist discourse leads to the conclusion that the trouble with Somalia is the nature of its culture, grounded in the clan system, with cruel individuals, proving divisive for projects of modern nation-building. However, this approach offers no answer to the following question: Since the lineage system has been part of Somali social organisation for centuries, why has this society not engaged in nihilistic fratricide before? Surely, there must have been power-seeking individuals in the past? (Samatar, 1992: 629). In essence, as the New Word Order puts Somalia on trial, along with Eritrea, Bosnia-Herzegovina, Afghanistan, Rwanda, and Haiti among others, and becomes enmeshed in their crises, historical and word system factors largely have been ignored. At least, the New World Order and its reliance on one version of the Enlightenment Project that focuses upon the dogmas rather than the ethos of the Project, is largely responsible for the characterization of Somalia as demonic and its clan leaders as devils.[1] The Order ignores, for example, the Enlightenment's search for honesty, probity, criticism, and analysis as it homogeneously imposes its control through facades of democracy, and often by economic blackmail or military force (yon Werlhof, 1991; Hollinger, 1994). While postmodern and poststructural analyses have been useful in explicating both the advantages and disadvantages of enlightenment doctrine (Hollinger, 1994), they suffer from two distinct problems. First, the analyses have focused upon symbolic considerations often to the exclusion of political economic factors. Second, discourse analyses typically are scathingly critical of elites and/or exclusion by elites, yet the analytical language employed has become for the most part itself exceedingly elite and exclusive. In the following discussion, we examine the dominant view of the Somali people and the sources of the problem in Somalia. We attempt to clarify and extend previous critiques of the dominant perspective, and suggest an alternative view that implies a different response to such a crisis. We suggest that comments and calls for action on crises such as the one identified and amplified by the New World Order in Somalia need to be considered in light of similar attempts to "normalize or develop" other indigenous peoples, e.g., the experiences of and reactions to some North American Indians and their impact on dominant world view and policy (Deloria, 1973; Nagel, 1997). In general, New World Order maintains an ostensible commitment to formal and abstract equality and another to substantive identities such as national ones whereby forms of exclusion and inequality are produced for diverse indigenous peoples (Maxted and Zegeye, 1997). The New World Order through the Enlightenment The New World Order, employing only part of Enlightenment discourse, continues stressing sameness and similarity rather than diversity across the human condition. Under the rubric of rationality there is the claim that the Order will pull in those who have traditionally been excluded, leading to an eventual melting pot where identity maintenance is minimal, since identity transformation is archaic or unrecognized. "Emancipation," and "rational social order" are central and interrelated concepts of the project with an undefined or varying concept of democracy touted as essential. Democracy for the Order typically is a rhetorical device for maintaining or gaining power. Often the reality is "elite democracy" as local elites compete with one another for power while attempting to service local capital and the requirements of international agencies such as the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank. Or, the imposition of external control is imposed without local participation. Democracy was ignored by the Order for "economic and strategic self-interest" in Iraq and Kuwait (Gills and Rocamora, 1992: 523). Despite overtures to the strength of "difference" from organizations presented as universal such as the United Nations, the original meaning of diversity contained and practiced within indigenous cultures of the world, for example, usually has been damned to the specter of deviance often shaded with demonic labels such as "savage" or "tribal." This domination of diversity can not be ignored by introducing dialectical nuances into the scheme or being "for" or "against" The New World Order or the Enlightenment (Foucault, 1984: 43; Foucault, 1988). Domination of nature, and derivatively domination of humans and their behavior, was not the end objective of the Enlightenment. Rather, a means for "human emancipation" from scarcity and the eradication of the supposed "arbitrariness" of nature were central goals. An unintended consequence of the Enlightenment's "emancipation" scheme, however, was that it opened the possibility of the self-alienation of humans from nature, from their own labor and from other human beings, the oppression and exploitation of human by human, and the destruction of what is now called the natural environment. (Tar, 1977). Despite these severe setbacks under modernity, progress was proclaimed through the sleight of hand of powerful new technologies that purport to free up more time for humans. Yet, many cultures with the most "leisure" time have had the lowest levels of technology. Similarly, the claim that human conflict was being resolved appears to be conflict management or denial (cf. Gurr, 1994, especially pages 365-367). In such presumption of progress, no one seems to be certain (including Enlightenment optimists) whether humans are encapsulating themselves in light or darkness. Blind faith in the dogmas of enlightenment, rather than a focus upon its ethos, is taken as an antidote to darkness and uncertain apocalypse. The homogenous agendas and practices of social and policy sciences and a hegemonic emergence of law are seen as instrumental to the creation of "rational order" in society. The myth of law, in Gramscian terms a "civil religion" under Enlightenment, is substituted for religious rituals. We now find atheists practicing the religious rituals of science as they simultaneously attempt to kill any and all god(s) or substitute the rational order of egoism and its sacred ceremonies for those religious ones they view as profane. The creation of "rational order" entails the construction of homogeneous nation-states, national identities, centralized bureaucracies, unified legal systems with a set of formal laws, and the institutionalization of market capitalism as "the" rational economic system (Thomas et al., 1987). Under The Order's criteria these indices presumably measure the stability and orderliness of a society. They are contrived to represent "civilized society" yet, the definition of civilized is usually a polemical device that ignores internal and external violence. The existence of a state that centrally enforces all these features under a "rule of law" is considered an active agent of The Order, and "in modernity, social and political stability is viewed as a result of 'law and order'" (Lauderdale, 1994:4). Therefore, one of the primary functions of the state is to maintain this political stability and enforce "law and order." The New World Order operates to enforce an idealized conception of law and order over all of the states within the political economy of the world system. Even in legal discourse, which acknowledges the politics of law and trials, the "rule of law" is presented as if it is value-free, neutral, and transcending institutionalized power relationships (Christenson, 1986). The "rule of law" is elevated tacitly as a universal benchmark to identify and classify deviance and trials in all societies, regardless of specific traditional polities. Balibar, albeit in a social class tone rather than mode of production analysis, notes that: the law is a system of rules, i.e., of material constraints, to which individuals are subjected. Legal ideology interprets and legitimizes this constraint, presenting it as a natural necessity inscribed in human nature and in the needs of society in general.... The legal ideology proves that the social order is not based on the existence of classes but precisely on that of individuals to which the law addresses itself. Its highest point in the legal representation is the state." (1987:739-740; cf. Thompson, 1987:64-67). A central problem with the concept of the "rule of law" is that it does not explain change in law or the differential application of law. The relationship between changes in modes of production and legal rules remains obfuscated by simply invoking the sacredness of the rule of law. The rule of law does not explain how concepts of legal equality have changed, e.g., legal status based on gender, ethnicity, race, age, or how exogenous factors will change it (Inverarity et al., 1983). Also, it does not inform us regarding, for example, such issues as discretion in enforcement or punishment, rather than to tell us about the form of the legal framework. The rule of law which requires that law simply be applied prospectively conflicts with natural law which "requires moral responsibility which cannot be excused through compliance with immoral positive law" (Adams, 1993: 312). The supposed new discovery of things and historical meanings by The Order, ironically, is usually only "rediscovery" (Lauderdale, 1994). Indigenous people long ago implemented "principles of confederation" and practiced "civil law" long before the late "discovery" of them by modernity (1994:10-11). Moreover, brazenly propagated is "the discovery" of indigenous people, whose existence and civilization long predated modernity, as "history." Their ancient civilization and history also were viewed either as "primitive" or "prehistory." Most importantly, despite being enmeshed in "endless internal ruptures and fragmentations," the New World Order endeavors to establish "universal order," a presumed "order" which it itself inherently lacks. The catastrophic conflicts among the various alternative systems (Democracy, Fascism, Socialism) attest to these "ruptures and fragmentations," as was manifested tragically in the two world wars, social and national revolutions, and state repressions against dissidents. The tragic consequences of these handful of events are unprecedented in the history of the whole world. The two world wars, which claimed some 57 million lives, began as European wars that were "universalized" throughout the globe. At the world level, the rule of law is suspended in debates over just versus unjust wars, and at the nation-state level the rule of law becomes a chimera as it variously labels dissidents as terrorists and deflects most serious accusations and analyses of state terrorism, i.e., the state's creation, control and use of terrorism for its own ends (Oliverio, 1998). Such actions raise serious questions about the ability of the New World Order to satisfy its commitments. Ironically, the agents of the New World Order view non-European traditional societies not only as "barbarian and primitive," but as also living in perpetual chaos and disorder. Vine Deloria observes that "in the [ostensibly] appalling indices of social disorder of the tribal peoples Westerners see only continued disruption and, being unaccustomed to viewing life as a totality, cannot understand the persistence of the tribal peoples in preserving their communities, lands and religions" (1973:300). This indigenous view includes not simply tolerance, but respect for diversity (which often is redefined as disorder). The indices, based upon Western ethnocentric construction of the concepts of disorder rather than diversity, now are being employed by the New World Order as justifications for extermination under the facade of progress. Similarly, Walter Rodney argues in his analysis of how Europe underdeveloped Africa that: tribalism is understood by Europeans to mean that each tribe still retains a fundamental hostility towards its neighboring tribes ... their accounts suggest that Europeans tried to make a nation out of the tribes, but they failed, because the various tribes had their age-long hatreds; and, as soon as the colonial power went, the nations returned to killing each other. To this phenomenon, Europeans often attach the word 'atavism', to carry the notion that Africans were returning to this primitive savagery. Even a cursory survey of the African past shows that such assertions are the exact opposite of the truth (1982:227). Somalia: A Nation Conceived for Crisis The Somalis are indigenous people in the Horn of Africa who have lived in part of the region since 500 B.C.; their name is derived from "Samaale," who was the legendary founder of the major pastoral clan families. Their population is estimated around 6 million, currently residing in Somalia "proper," Ethiopia, Eritrea, Kenya, and Djibouti. Two-thirds of Somalis are pastoralists, who herd camels, goats, cattle, and sheep to support their lives. Their pastoral occupation is influenced by the dry land, hot climate, and scarcity of water in the region. Except along the banks of the two main rivers (Juba and Shebelle), the soil is not suitable for agriculture and therefore hardly cultivable. The Somali pastoralists follow their annual migratory cycles, they remain with their herds in the pasture of the hinterland during the rainy season(October-November) and spend the remaining months in the proximity of the Red Sea shores, where water holes are located. Said Samatar and David Leitin note that: in this land of hardy vegetation, steaming sand dunes, and sun-baked coastal plains, the Somalis have evolved during the centuries a way of life peculiarly suited to their demanding environment: on the one hand a trans-human pastoralism designed to maximize the meager resources of water wells and pasturelands for the pastoralists and their herds and, on the other, a social organization that encourages collective action and mutual aid (Samatar and Leitin, 1987:22). Somali's pastoral life is symbolized by the camel; the camel holds a central place not only in the economic sphere but in the cultural expressions of the Somalis. Somalis use the camel as a term of reference in their poetry, songs, and political vocabularies. Moreover, camels are used as a medium of exchange, e.g., as a form of payment for "blood money." Somalis call the camel the "mother of man." Two milch-camels support a family of ten with their nutritious milk. The "place" of the camel is understandable from the practices of diversity in other cultures. For many North American Indians the buffalo was central to their symbolic and ceremonial life often having a place in creation traditions (Thornton, 1987). Josephy (1984: 89) notes that, for example, in 1978, various Plains tribal members still needed buffalo meat for specific religious feasts: "Some ceremonies require the presence of a live buffalo among the participants."(2) Unlike many African indigenous peoples, whose differences and conflicts stem from ethnic segmentation and the struggle for power, the Somalis are people of the same ethnicity. They speak the same Somali language and preponderantly have followed Islam as a religious faith since the twelfth century. However, the Somalis are segmented among lineages, which is an organizing principle of clan life. There are six major clans (Dir, Hawiye, Isaaq, Darood, Digil, and Rahanwayan) and approximately 56 sub-clans. Samatar and Leitin observe that "genealogy constitutes the heart of the Somali social system and is the basis of the Somali collective predilection to internal fissions and internecine sectionary conflicts as well as of the unity of thought and action among Somalis - a unity that borders on xenophobia" (1987:29). The Somalis' primary allegiance is to their respective clans and sub-clans; and their identities are also derived from such clan affiliation. An individual is identified as a Somali only after becoming a member of a certain clan. The clan system has its own defense mechanisms based on clan solidarity or exclusivity from outside threats or penetration (cf. Samatar and Leitin, 1987:31). In contrast, focusing upon the relevance of the household economy and its connection to the concepts of community and kinship rather than simply clan, Abdi Samatar states that: The significance of the household economy in pre-colonial Somali social life rested, at least to a great extent, on the fact that very few were not engaged in productive activity, and they certainly did not dominate the affairs of the community. In fact, those who were not productive, and consequently unable to care for their households, had no standing in the community, let alone the ability to command any authority. In other words, being a competent pastoral manager or good peasant was a necessary prerequisite for any leadership position (1992: 639). The "Old" New World Order was introduced directly to Somalia via European colonialism in 1889. The introduction included forceful occupation of the region and subjugation of the people by armed force. First the Italians (in 1889), and subsequently the British (1899) and the French (1900) carved the region into four pieces and began their colonization, a process which was euphemistically termed as "the civilizing mission" of the "primitive natives." That decade was a period when the colonizing project by European powers continued under the rubric of "the Scramble for Africa" following their conference in Berlin in 1884. Sir Henry Maine in his study of the development of law discusses how Roman law in its concept of "occupatio" developed into a law to justify and preserve the acquisition of private property, such as land. According to this legal principle, every thing must have an owner; if anything does not, it may be claimed by the first occupant (Maine, 1909). However, when it came to "acquiring" (colonizing) colonies, the colonizers needed an expediting fiction, or a "legal fiction," which manifested itself in the contrived hierarchization of "civilized citizens" and "primitive natives" (Lauderdale, 1994:15). The mythology of modern law was reinforced by portraying "the primitive, to take a figure of the other, [as] uncontrolled, fickle, irresponsible, of nature... The European is disciplined, constant, self-responsible, of culture, and so on" (Fitzpatrick, 1992: 30). Variation in positive or stigmatizing identity was also contingent upon numerous forms of economic organization, labor control, and symbolic concern. Consider the instance of primitive accumulation of indigenous food: The British did not own the means of propagating such crops. This technicality did not deter them. They simply refused to recognize any proprietary rights of the people or even of the rulers of these peripheral lands. The plant explorers were charged with obtaining the plants by any means possible... (Perelman, 1983: 17). Grazing land that was communally owned was considered devoid of legal titles and indigenous peoples were left without any entitlement to ownership. Moreover, under such classification, the dispossession of territories from the indigenous people was justified as liberating the land for productive use that otherwise was perceived as lying fallow and being valueless under the hands of "lethargic primitives." Thus, colonial acquisition and capitalist privatization of land and other natural resource were "legally" sanctified while forcefully instituted to be commodified as any other product, mediated only through the fetishism of money. Land and its sacred identity of place was negated by the colonists with propriety of ownership and production becoming the central concept. On the contrary, indigenous people, as Vine Deloria notes, have "spiritual unity" with the land they inhabit and honor its sacredness (1973: 295). In this century we find liberation theologians primarily in Central America calling for land to revert to those people who work it, rather than simply own it, and subsequently we find peasants and indigenous people suggesting that their work "with" the land is sacred (Lauderdale, 1994; 1997). Yet, in Haiti where Aristide spoke of a similar theology of liberation in the early 1990s, the theology typically was rationalized away by the New World Order and reduced to a communist identity, despite the obvious conundrum of the spirit of communism. Aristide's religious work often was identified as undemocratic, rather than communitarian or spiritual. As the Order tried to impose its dogma and "develop" the North American Indians and the Central American Indians and peasants, it now returns to other places such as Haiti with hopes of transforming the identity of Aristide and the Haitians. Yet, land, especially the relationship of its meaning to social identity in places such as Haiti and Somalia, remains unresolved. The control of the definition of land also is central to other concepts such as discovery or development. For example, Benjamin Franklin, who often is resurrected as a paragon of the Enlightenment vision, "rationalized" colonization by asserting that colonialists who acquire land, even by forcefully removing "the natives" if necessary, "may be properly called the fathers of the nation" (Hunt, 1987: 47). This so-called development process is one way the legendary European "founding fathers" were concocted, who otherwise, in the eyes of the indigenous people, were often exploiters or demolishers of traditional societies. And, the British colonial powers projected onto their "civilizing mission" an ironic feature when they proclaimed that their colonial presence in Somalia induced an industrial revolution. Yet, the facade of an immaculate implanting of an "industrial revolution" was nothing more than the production of candles, matches, bottle corks, wine, and mm (British Military Administration, 1944: 62). Regional partitioning by European colonialism and the implantation of a colonial state engendered the perpetual disruption of the normal economic cycle and social life of the Somali pastoralists. During colonial role the Somalis were considered colonial subjects, and were racially segregated from the Europeans. The majority of Somalis, not having contact with the colonial administration, became increasingly alienated. Only an elite portion had access to modern formal education and administrative positions. Elite implementation of the institutionalization of private property directly negated their traditional communal land ownership system. Under the traditional "economy" of the Somalis, the "household was a basic unit of (livestock) ownership; whereas the grazing lands and water resources were collectively utilized by the members of the clan" (A. Samatar, 1989: 16). In general, the fertile agricultural land and the grazing land with the water holes fell under the control of the colonial administration or was designated as an enticement for European colonial settlers. Similarly, once the livestock export began to generate revenue for the colony, this commodification process pulled the self-sufficient pastoralists into a dependent relationship with the domestic and international market (cf. von Werlhof, 1991). Economic dependency was compounded by the demarcation and enforcement of international borders that inhibited the free movement of the pastoral people and so disrupted their occupation. Wallerstein cogently remarks that: the political boundaries were drawn primarily to include as much territory as could be conquered or negotiated diplomatically. Since the lines were established by each European power essentially out of fear of a claim of sovereignty by another European power, they were frequently arbitrary in terms of the previous lines drawn by the African states now enclosed or divided." (1986:16). There was not only conquest (called "pacification"), but there was also the deliberate disruption of existing social organizations similar to the disruption and conquest of American indigenous people by European colonialists. Hunt observes that "white Americans had not inherited the fabled empty continent, rather by their presence and policies, they had emptied it" (1987:53). Justification for colonialism was claimed by identifying the Somalis as people with "inherent lawlessness," and with a benign racist label, in strikingly similar fashion to the characterization of North American Indians by Europeans as "noble savages." The characterization of a "handsome, unreliable race" was imputed to the Somalis (British Military Administration, 1944: 49-50). The colonial period in Somalia was marked by the resistance of the indigenous people. Somalis notably struggled under the leadership of a religious leader and a famous poet, Hassan Abdille, from around 1900 until 1920. Abdille resisted the British and the Italian colonialists through armed struggle. The British referred to him as the "mad mullah." The label seemed to originate in view of how "primitive" indigenous people could resist a "benevolent civilizing mission" unless they are totally psychotic, much as the European labeling of indigenous North Americans as "savages" stemmed from indigenous resistance (Deloria, 1973; Nagel, 1997). Part of the resistance was directed at the manner in which Europeans identified what type of order was the defining criteria of civilization.(3) A central component of the new order is the separation of humanity from nature with human identity constructed as capable of order and nature as naturally disordered. Vine Deloria observes that Europeans could not understand the persistence of the indigenous people and their insistence on the preservation of land and a traditional way of life (1973). Nonetheless, Despite numerous attempts of holocaust proportion to destroy these indigenous people, they have persisted. Their social organization and cultural values based on thousands of years of learning the lessons of nature are central to this persistence. These lessons were ignored and suffocated by colonizers who prefer to be called modern people (Lauderdale, 1994:15). Somalis also incessantly resisted the political, economic, and cultural domination of Europeans and their claims to homogenous order (see, Samatar and Leitin, 1987:42). The Somalis opposed, for example, all forms of Italian and British rule, including colonial legal systems that held individuals as culpable and defined political resistance as a crime. Under indigenous law, individuals were not culpable for their offenses, rather the "dia-paying" group was collectively accountable, and political resistance was a civil matter to be mediated by elderly councils. When Somalia finally achieved its independence as a nation in 1960, there were only a few Somalis who were able to work successfully in the centralized bureaucratic administration, inherited from colonialism. The construction of a unified Somali nation, organized under a central state, and its continuation in the post-colonial era was the work of colonial powers. The colonial powers, however, did not differentiate between the commitment to formal and abstract equality, and the one to homogenous substantive identities such as national citizenship that resulted in the licensing of exclusion with varying degrees of stigma. Family loyalty, for example, was redefined negatively as non-rational attachment to kin-ship and then amplified by proclaiming that kinship, often defined as clan, worked against national interests. Somali nationalism seemed more a product of the Enlightenment's dogmas than the concern of Somali aspiration. After an experience of two elections and a parliamentary state of eight years, Somalia fell under General Siad Barre's military dictatorship in 1969. Siad Barre ruled Somalia with an iron-fist through his ruling party, the Somali Revolutionary Socialist Party, for the ensuing 22 years until he was overthrown in January 1991. Consider the characterization of "Third World" states as the vehicle of nation-hood by O'Donnel (1987) as it applies to Somalia's state under General Siad Barre. "The state in the 'Third World' is a profoundly unrepresentative entity (to its colonial origins) whose historical mission is to be the agent that produces a synthesis of what is a heterogeneous civil society. It has meant a creation of a nationhood" (1987: 213). In short, the central state in Somalia with its homogenizing mission through crushing people into the "national" mold is incompatible with the freedom-loving and heterogeneously kin-based Somalis. Inversely, what had been witnessed in post-independence Somalia was the utilization of the state as a center vying for power and resources among the different clan leaders. The extension of the traditional rivalry among the different clans within the centralized state creates conflict over the allocation of political power and the use of national resources (Doornbus, 1993). In the late 1990s, security for the affluent and expatriates in the era of the dismantling of state police and the army has led to the Mooriyaan (gunpersons) and the "technicals" (e.g., using machine-gun-mounted trucks) who provide armed escort for money. Clearly, the leadership of the clans have been transformed from organized kinship groups led by traditional elders into the new leadership assumed by former state military and bureaucratic elites. General Barre's rule in the 1970s and 1980s usually was characterized as stable from the perspective of the Western core countries. This view emanated from the middle of the cold war period with considerable military assistance from the former U.S.S.R. and the U. S. and was based upon Barre's shift of alliances between the two military super-powers. The Soviet Union, for example, was a strong ally and major supplier of arms to General Barre until 1977. Between 1967 and 1976 Somalia imported $181 million worth of arms from the U.S.S.R. (Lefebvre, 1991: 44). However, when the U.S.S.R. shifted its alliance to Ethiopia, Somalia turned to the U.S. and found an ally whose preoccupation was to check the influence of the U.S.S.R. in the Persian Gulf region. In 1980, the U.S. signed an agreement with the same dictator, General Barre, an accord based on access-arms exchange. Over the next seven years Somalia purchased $500 million worth of arms from the U.S. (Lefebvre, 1991: 241). Smyth and Goose (1994) present a relevant analysis of how the United Nations fails to restrain its members states from engaging in lucrative arms trade, especially the process by which some of the member states supply weapons to conflicting groups in Somalia, the Sudan, and Rwanda. Barre maintained his power, domestically, by brutally silencing his opponents and relying on his Darod clan, and its Marehan sub-clan. In 1988 10,000 people were killed and 110,000 fled to Ethiopia as the conflict escalated between Barre's regime and the opposing clans. In the late 1980s, however, his military disintegrated into different clan militias, the civil service was in disarray, and his cabinet vied for fragmented power and depleted resources. Despite promises for constitutional review, elections, and legalization of parties between 1989 and 1990, General Barre was overthrown in January 1991. Subsequently, a civil war intensified among the different clan-based political factions. During this civil war, from May 1988 to December 1989, according to Africa Watch, between 50,000 and 60,000 civilians died (Makinda, 1992). Currently, political parties in Somalia are based on new clan allegiances. The conflict among the different political parties is the reflection of tension among the different clans and novel economic interests and political views engendered by the New World Order. There is infighting within the same clans among the fragmented army units and their respective political parties. For instance, the Hawiye clan-based United Somali Congress party took power in Somalia's capital, Mogadishu, in the wake of General Barre's flight. The Hawiye clan has six sub-clans in central Somalia, two of which (Abgal and Habr Gedir) are bitter enemies. General Aideed leads the Habr Gedir sub-clan and Mohammed "Bod" the Abgal one. The Northern part of Somalia under the Isaaq clan-based Somali National Movement formed its own separate state in May 1991. The large scale conflict was an eruption of the hidden and gradual crisis emerging from the inception of the unified and repressive nation state. The crisis in Somalia was conceived within the formation of the centralized nation-state under which all the different clans were forcefully enclosed. The gradual build-up of the crisis was not detected by the chevaliers of The Order (including the foreign policy makers of the U.S. and the former U.S.S.R.) due to their overriding concern with world hegemony, geopolitical domination, and larger market forces. It is ironic that the ostensibly united Somalia of 1960 under one central state was deserted by all foreign powers when it exploded in the crisis of 1991. Initially, the United Nations and the U.S. minimized their public involvement in Somalia and the U.S. did not fully enter the conflict until December of 1992 when it announced that U.S. troops would arrive to protect food convoys sent to the starving nation. The U.S. approach to resolve the conflict had been within the New World Order, a scheme re-constructed by the Reagan and Bush administrations. The re-packaged New World Order, designed under such ??? as "the rule of law," "peace," "stability" "world democracy," and "equal sovereignty rights," is "a crusading movement" to promote world hegemony (cf. Augelli and Murphy, 1988). This new form of (post Cold War) global expansion intends to recreate the world after the images of the New Order's system of governance and open market economy. International institutions such as the United Nations, the World Bank, and the IMF are part of the global hegemony working as instruments of rationalization to realize these two basic interests (Lauderdale and Amster, 1997; see Lefebvre, 1991:275 regarding international financial institutions, bi-lateral development assistance, and the policing role of the U.N.). More generally, core countries that strive for world hegemony continue to attempt to use the U.N. as the peace keeper or social control agent, e.g., note the attempt of the U.S. to influence the U.N. in the 1998 bombings of its embassies in Kenya and Tanzania). Under such a New World Order the notion of "equal sovereignty rights" of states is designed at least to console Third World countries, or at most is simply a hegemonic facade, to help veil domination (Krasner, 1985: 62). As the world turns, so does the hegemony created by world powers. Whether economic and political control at the world level has been largely in the hands of the Chinese, the Spanish or the English, or other countries and confederations at other times (cf. Frank, 1998; Gills and Frank, 1992), such control has been a central factor in obscuring the multifaceted impact of globalization. The claim that globalization, touted as a primary force in the new world order, is new or that it will develop the underdeveloped nations is misleading (Abu-Lughod, 1989; Woodward, 1996). The enlightenment hegemony of Europe employed by various nations has shed little light, but much friction upon Somalia and the new world disorder. This (dis)order is reflected in Gramsci's observation that the old order is dead, but the new order cannot yet be born (also, see Seidman, 1977). Closing Argument: Is the New World Order Culpable? A conceptual scheme that ignored diversity underscored the formation of a central state in Somalia. The internal conflicts among the segmented clans are now concentrated and amplified in the arena of the pervasive state, a conflict that was engendered mainly by competition over resources and power, and exacerbated by the intrusion of the homogenous demands of the New World Order. The conflict intensified in a short span of time into a larger scale, involving virtually all of the clans in Somalia. The problem continues today as, for example, fighters loyal to Hussein Aidid, who is the son of deceased General Aidid and his successor, fight the Reewin Resistance Army around the southwestern regions of Bay and Bakool. Such conflicts and ensuing crises are unprecedented in the history of the Somali people. The Order facilitated chaos in Somalia. In this respect, we clearly disagree with scholars who attribute the cause of the crisis principally to the internal clan segmentation itself. Similarly, Makinda's attribution of Barre's dictatorial rule alone as the root of the tragedy is inadequate for explaining the endemic crisis in Somalia; the argument does not explain why "there was no mechanism for resolving internal conflict" (Makinda, 1993: 12). Disregarding the destruction of kinship, ignoring or minimizing the role of the world's political economy, and under the cloak of homogeneity, diversity has been reduced to the label of "deviance." As with most of Africa, the cause of economic and financial crises in Somalia usually is attributed to externally conditioned export-oriented and export-based development policies. Or, in the words of the World Bank in 1994 the problem is "a massive loss of competitiveness." In other words, because of the emphasis given to commodity exchange and austerity programs, countries such as Somalia are not able to produce even enough food for their own people. And, in 1998 Somalia faces its worst harvest in the past five years. Clearly, economic marginalization continues to contribute to the escalation of the conflicts (Bestman and Cassanelli, 1997). Second, The introduction of The "Order" via large scale military technology with attendant institutionalized violence (e.g., via standing armies), directly contributed to the intensification and magnification of violence as a modality of ostensible conflict resolution (Lauderdale and Cruit, 1993). It also induced the destruction of human lives and impoverishment of people. Moreover, Smyth and Goose (1994) explicate the reasons why the U.N. continues to fail to restrain core member nations from supplying weapons to conflicting groups in Somalia, the Sudan, and Rwanda. Third, Somalis could not turn to their traditional institutions or associations such as the "gurti" (a network of elders from diverse kinship groups) to negotiate their conflict peacefully and administer their lives self-sufficiently, since their policies have been incapacitated by the domination of the central state and its bureaucracy. The basis of "pre-colonial social justice was the self-reliance of the household, coupled with systemic checks on those who wanted to aid the resources of others" (A. Samatar, 1992: 640). Moreover, during the past hundred years, the authority of the informal social contract called "heer," which binds each member of a clan to one another and regulates relationships with other clans, increasingly has been eroded. Similarly, the all-adult assembly, called the "Shir," which is accessible to the participation of all clan members and peacefully mediates conflicts among clans, was emasculated. The traditional justice system that holds groups culpable (which rendered collective social responsibility and deterrence) was centrally challenged by the system of individual liability, thereby diminishing its significance and effectiveness (cf. Oliverio and Lauderdale, 1990). Finally, the Somali political and military leaders increasingly are modern elites who emerged from alien political, military, and economic institutions that were transplanted by Enlightenment dogmas. As they are formally educated, trained and acculturated individuals, they are the products of Enlightenment's culture and soldiers of the New World Order. Their concern, and the modalities they employ, to identify Somali problems and the management rather than resolution of crises is within the Order's paradigm - the central state, military violence, and the market economic framework of the world system. It should be remembered that: At no time in the recent history of Somalia has nearly one-third to one-half of the population died or been in danger of perishing due to famine caused by civil war (A. Samatar, 1992: 625). In the summer of 1993, the fifteen Somali political factions were involved in the process of negotiation in Addis Ababa, with the United States as the principal mediator. However, claims of conflict resolution began fading over the summer of 1994. The Security Council of the United Nations decided on September 30, 1994, to leave its troops in Somalia only one more month, but the U.S. refused to support the latest extension of the Order. The Security Council set a condition that unless the warring clan factions ceased their fighting, the U.N. would abandon Somalia entirely.(5) This abrupt resolution again challenged the Order of the New World, especially in the face of the seemingly continual eruption of crises throughout the world. And, to the extent that the U.N. represents the New World Order, it may be impossible to keep the Order on trial as it positions itself once again to move to other jurisdictions, or claims that no current law covers its current jurisdiction. In December of 1997, three of the faction leaders, Ali Mahdi, Hussein Aidid, and Osman Atto signed a peace agreement in Cairo. Although over a dozen similar pacts have been created in the past, there was some hope that a meeting in Mogadishu would implement this one. Those meetings were governed by Egyptians who had important insight into the deeper problems but once again peace was short lived. Sporadic fights emerged from other factions and the Somaliland Republic in the North did not endorse the peace agreement. Another convention was planned for early 1998 in Baidoa to plan for a national government; however, before the meeting took place fighting broke out over which faction would gain leadership of the convention. In addition, despite the efforts of organizations such as the War-torn Societies Project (a joint project of the U.N. and the Programme for Strategic and International Security Studies in Geneva) to provide international advice, the assistance does not appear to address the underlying problems. By late 1998, the meeting in Baidoa had been postponed for the third time. The traditional kinship groups in Somalia turned to traditional elders for advice and assistance but currently their role also is usurped by former state military and bureaucratic elites. The politicalization of "clan" differences by such elites continues to amplify clannish sentiments (e.g., as they fight over control of the six newspapers and radio stations in Mogadishu) and intensify conflicts. The attempted replacement of sacred place and kinship identity of Somalis with the identity of the New World Order that emphasizes rational (self-interested) and egoistic (self-maximizing) individuals, i.e., Western individualism (Thomas et al., 1987) has led not to a melting pot, but a boiling pot. It appears, once again, that most Somalis do not identify with the concept of an atomistic individual or highly abstract general terms such as the state or national citizen. The Somalis, as with many other ethnic and indigenous groups throughout the world, do not find a meaningful sense of life by being defined as a modern individual via the state. Sustenance, solidarity, and security, for example, are located and identified with sacred places and extended families for many diverse groups such as the Somalis. Any viable alternative to disentangling Somalia from its current and future crises would benefit from recognition and accommodation to the traditional way of life and system of governance. Otherwise, the ostensible conflict resolution will be, at best, short-term and partial and, at worst, a facade. NOTES 1 Our names are listed alphabetically. We would like to thank Fausto Oliverio for providing us with his oral history regarding the relationship between Italy and Somalia. We thank Randall Amster, David Goldberg, Jody Lameman, Bin Liang, and Annamarie Oliverio for their incisive comments on a number of drafts of this work and Andre Gunder Frank for providing essential background information. We also appreciate the useful critique by Raymond Corrado who attempted to define the limits on our criticisms of the Enlightenment Project. 2 Any analysis of the Enlightenment runs the risk of pandering to histories of the feudal period with pictures of crude struggles over scarce resources or the prattle of histories of the period with portrayals of simple but honorable lives. We accept the varying and clearly more formidable challenges provided by texts such as A Distant Mirror and In the Absence of the Sacred in this discussion. We suggest that Enlightenment through the New World Order has two major inherent self-negations in its conception. The first is that it has been imposing its monolithic conceptual scheme in every part of the world, on societies with radically different social systems. This imposition principally takes the use of naked force or technologically bolstered mega-power violence, including and up to committing genocide. Or, it imposes itself hegemonically through diffusion of ideas and educational training (ideological), and through indirect rule by the cooptation of indigenous "modern elites," albeit in what Goldberg (1993: 104) terms a "universal reductionist" mode. Regardless of the way it imposes itself, the dogmas of the Enlightenment Project enforced by the Order has brought agonizing oppression and chronic disruption in the traditional lives of indigenous people. Secondly, Enlightenment via the Order not only has no respect for non-European traditions but neither for its own (Harvey, 1989:11-12). 3 For numerous North American Indian Nations on the Great Plains, the buffalo was the source of clothing, housing, eating utensils, sleds, parfleche as a carryall, musical instruments, cosmetics, jewelry, armor, masks, and dung for fuel (cf. Thornton, 1987). Skins sometimes were used to record the events of a person's life in pictorial form. Some oral history suggests that the animal provided everything, except water and poles for housing. The most glaring example of animal reduction-probably the one most destructive to American Indians was the near extinction of the buffalo, which culminated during the last half of the 19th century, especially to the Plains Indians (Thornton, 1987: 51-52). For some of the Nations the sacred bundle was made of buffalo skin. Buffalo Gap in the southeastern part of the Black Hills now of South Dakota is the place where the buffalo came in spring which began the ceremonial year of the Plains Indians. Buffalo Gap has been seen as the starting point of the Great Race that determined the primacy between two legged and four legged creatures at the beginning of the world. Spiritual relationships with other animals and persons were associated with physical places such as Buffalo Gap (Deloria, 1973: 273). 4 The use of deviant or demonic labels is a common device for marginalizing or excluding protest. Calling a leader the "Mad Mullah" in Somalia or the "Red Devil" in Indian Country, U.S.A., is but one attempt. And, the demonic label often is attached to leaders who are perceived as having spiritual characteristics. In Elkswatawa or The Prophet of the West (1836), for example, as James Strange French tries to present the last stand of the Indian in Ohio country he reveals the demonization of the "spiritual" leaders and the ascription of savage in contrast to civilized identities. The practice also applies to the pejorative identification of entire cultures. North American history is replete with examples of attempts to identify Indians as savages (cf. Pearce, 1953; Kinietz, 1965). Yet, as Dennis Banks explained in his defense following criminal charges in "The Wounded Knee Trial," he was a Lakota. Lakota means "allies," while the word "Sioux" is French meaning "cut throat" (Christenson, 1986). The power to control identity may constrain or otherwise direct action in areas where there are a number of possible courses of identification. The fight over an accurate historical record brings a variety of perspectives into the picture, including those people who are more concerned that indigenous people do not glorify their history. Baxter (1994: 174), for example, in commenting on the Oromo and political activists states that "it would be remarkable in the circumstances if a romanticized, primordial past were not fabricated." 5 In 1992, United Nations Secretary General, Boutros Boutros-Ghali chastised the U.N. Security Council for devoting disproportionate levels of attention and resources to the former Yugoslavia while paying little attention to the growing crisis in Somalia. He remarked that their focus was upon the rich people's war. His comment also has led to an examination of the issue of "race" in the U.N.'s varying response to such crises. REFERENCES Abu-Lughod, Janet 1989 Before European Hegemony. New York: Oxford University Press. Adams, Kif Augustine 1993 "What is Just? The Rule of Law and Natural Law in the Trial of Former East German Border Guards." Stanford Journal of International Law 29:271-291. Augelli, Enrico & Murphy, Craig 1988 America's Quest: For Supremacy and the Third World. London: Printer Publishers. Balibar, Etienne 1987 "What is State Power?" In The Political Economy of Law, edited by Ghai, Yash et al. Delhi: Oxford University Press. Baxter, P.T.W. 1994 "The Creation and Constitution of Oromo Nationality." Pp. 167-186 in Ethnicity and Conflict in the Horn of Africa, edited by Katsuyoshi Fukui and John Markakis. Athens, OH: Ohio University Press. Bestman, Catherine, and Lee Cassanelli (eds.) 1996 The Struggle for Land in Southern Somalia: The War Behind the War. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. British Military Administration 1944 The First to be Freed. London: His Majesty's Stationery Office. Christenson, Ron 1986 Political Trials. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction. Deloria, Vine Jr. 1973 God is Red. New York: Grosset and Dunlap. (c) 1999 Information Access Company. All rights reserved. This article may only be stored on a computer network for a maximum of 30 days. Quellen:IAC TRADE AND INDUSTRY DATABASE JOURNAL OF ASIAN & AFRICAN STUDIES 01/05/1999 P157 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 08Dez1998 INDIA: Rural uplift - Case for state help (1041). By SAMIT KAR. An International Workshop in Bangkok this month will find ways of making decentralised rural development self-reliant - villagers should make do without "support from above". Though "rural development" has no universally accepted definition, the term is often used to define a government-aided strategy to enable a specific group of people - poor rural men and women - to gain for themselves and their children, more of what they want and need. It involves helping the poor in the rural areas to demand and control more of the benefits of rural development. As a result, the process of rural development should represent the entire gamut of change by which a social system moves towards an all-round "better" quality of life. But how will the rural poor become self-supporting without help from above? This is the focal point of discussion of this workshop. Meanwhile, when governments of the Third World are shedding their age old social commitment to alleviate mass poverty, a new set of catchwords has emerged. These terms have little relevance to the process of grassroot governance. Expressions like "participatory rural appraisal", "community participation", "entitlements" and "development from below" are now fashionable in the realm of development planning but considering the nature of the "clientele", i.e., the takers, what do "participation" and "opportunity" mean to them? The donor agency-induced model of development with stress on PRA was interpreted by one such scholar as follows. Development can be richer and meaningful only through the participation of the clientele of development. It is a challenge for all those who act as facilitators of development right from a policy-maker down to a village-level worker. But in the process of development in a deprived society who is the clientele? What are its basic attributes? An average Indian villager represents one of the worst forms of human resources in terms of earning, education, health, calorie intake and social opportunities. Without some degree of government support, how can he survive? What does participation mean to him? Yet development is now considered by donor agencies to be meaningful only through peoples' participation. PANCHAYATS There had therefore been a growing impression that PRA techniques are nothing more than a hoax. That planning can only become real if the exercise is done by the people, of the people and for the people. But in reality, much is imposed from above at the behest of donor agencies. In India more stress has been laid on internal resource mobilisation. This, for example, partly motivated the 73rd Constitution (Amendment) Act, 1992, better known as the Panchayati Amendment Act. Section 243I of the Act led to the formation of State Finance Commissions, which were empowered to review the financial position of the local bodies every five years. Section 243G of the Panchayati Amendment Act says: subject to the provision of this Constitution, the legislature of a state may, by law, give panchayats such powers as may be necessary to enable them to function as institutions of self-government. Such laws may contain provisions for the devolution of powers and responsibilities upon panchayats at the appropriate level, subject to certain conditions. Section 243H states that the legislature of a state may, by law authorise a panchayat to levy and collect taxes, duties, tolls and fees in accordance with certain procedures and subject to prescribed limits. This section also provides the scope for giving panchayats powers pertaining to grants-in-aid from the consolidated fund of the state. On the basis of these three Sections, SFCs have to address the issue of identifying taxes, duties, toll and fees levied by the state government. The net proceeds of these imposts may be divided between the state government and the local bodies. In such cases, the SFCs have to decide about the principles governing the distribution, assignment and release of grants and the measures needed to improve the financial position of the local bodies. The commissions also have to give their recommendations on any other matter referred to it by the state governments. STUDY Accordingly, the West Bengal Finance Commission was constituted on 30 May 1994 under the chairmanship of Dr Satyabrata Sen. The Commission submitted its report to the state government on 27 November 1995, which was accepted with the publication of a notification on 22 July 1996. The report of the Commission cited a study by the Institute of Social Sciences, New Delhi. According to the study, the average annual income per gram panchayat - the lowest tier of local government - varies from a low of Rs 1299 in Madhya Pradesh to a high of Rs 6.80 lakhs in Kerala, a very wide distribution even allowing for local variations. In most states, the gram panchayats were excessively dependent on government grants. The exceptions being those in Gujarat, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra and Kerala where the gram panchayats mobilised 30 per cent or more of their revenue by their own efforts. In West Bengal, the average resource mobilisation per gram panchayat was about Rs 12,000 which is only a small fraction of the grants-in-aid inflow. The West Bengal Finance Commission's recommendation explicitly underlined the fact that such a lackadaisical approach will henceforth not be tolerated. The publication of the reports of various SFCs highlighted the policy desideratum of making the institutions of decentralisation self-sufficient. However, self-sufficiency or not, given that the bulk of the rural population is poor and malnutrited, the government cannot abdicate its social responsibility. The experience of Latin American countries in the late 60s and early 70s deserves mention in this context. Proponents of the Dependency School such as Samir Amin, Andre Gunder Frank and Dos Santos criticised the programme of the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America which recommended the withdrawal of government support to the underprivileged. Not too long after, Latin America experienced a protracted period of recession and political repression. The same can happen in India. Ominously, donor agencies are again repeating the catch phrase of "participatory approach". Copyright(C) 1998 THE STATESMAN (INDIA). (c) 1998 Chamber World Network International Ltd. Quellen:ASIA INTELLIGENCE WIRE THE STATESMAN 08/12/1998 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 02Nov1998 INDIA: Yet they have been the worst offenders of all. One might naively think that for the study of economic history as it really was, the place to turn is to economic historians. Yet they have been the worst offenders of all. The vast majority of self-styled `economic historians' totally neglect the history of most of the world, and the remaining minority distort it altogether. Most economic historians seem to have no perspective - not even a European one - of the world at all. Instead, their `economic history' is almost altogether confined to the West...The rest of the world does not exist for them. The author of one of the most note worthy examples of this kind of Eurocentric economic history recently won the Nobel Prize for economics. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History was written by the 1993 Nobel laureate in economics Douglass C North with Robert Paul Thomas (1973)... They clearly state "the development of an efficient economic organization in Western Europe accounts for the rise of West"... The rest of the world and its demographic upturn as well was not there for them. What is more serious is that the small minority of economic historians who do refer to "the Rest" very seriously distort both "the East" and its economic relations with "the West." Their perspective on the "world economy" is that it emerged out of Europe and that Europe built a world economy around itself.... Marxist economic history may seem different, but it is equally, indeed even more, Eurocentric...The very existence of a world economic system was explicitly denied by Marx and only belatedly acknowledged by Lenin. Andre Gunder Frank in Re Orient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. (c) 1998 The Times of India Group. Quellen:ECONOMIC TIMES 02/11/1998 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 25Okt1998 INDIA: Decline of the East. IN THIS book Andre Gunder Frank has turned received Eurocentric historiography and social theory upside down by using a "globological" perspective. the author asks us to ReORIENT our views away from Eurocen-trism to see the Rise of the West as a mere blip in what was, and is again becoming, an Asia-centric world. Frank's thesis is that the West first bought itself a third-class seat on the Asian economic train, then leased a whole railway carriage, and only in the nineteenth century managed to displace Asians from the locomotive. He argues that the industrial revolution and its eventual use by the Europeans to achieve a position of dominance in the world economy cannot be adequately explained on the basis only of factors "internal" to Europe. Frank explains the rise of the West from 1400 onwards in world economic and demographic terms, with a sweeping historical perspective that places it in clear conjunction with the decline of the East around 1800. European states, he says, used the silver extracted from the American colonies to buy entry into an expanding Asian market, which already flourished in the global economy by means of the very productive commercial and institutional mechanisms that were supposedly unique to Europe. Then, as the East entered into a decline phase of cyclical world economy, the nations of te West resorted to import substitution and export promotion in the world market to become New Industrialising Economies. This is certainly an exciting reassessment of our global economic past and anyone interested in economic and social history, and in Asia cannot afford to ignore this work - Frank's "best book" if we are to go by his dedicatory note. (c) 1998 The Times of India Group. Quellen:ECONOMIC TIMES 25/10/1998 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 25Mai1998 INDIA: A neither-here-nor-there account. By Prasun Sonwalkar. It is common sense to assume that a book must tell the public a little more than what is already well known. This is more so for books on current affairs and by authors who are not read simply because they are great stylists. Sadly, S S Gill does not add to the reader's knowledge of corruption which is all-pervasive and obsessively discussed and commented upon in democratic India. This is all the more disappointing because as a former IAS officer, he has had a long stint in that great abode of corruption in the country, the bureaucracy. Any hope of discovering new facts or an insider's account of corruption in the bureaucracy is dashed when Gill begs the question by asking somewhat pompously and rhetorically: "Would it be permissible to infer that this service (IAS) may not be as corrupt as it is generally presumed to be?" Gill is even now right at the centre of an amazingly bureaucratic organisation, Prasar Bharati (encompassing Doordarshan and All India Radio) of which he is the CEO. Gill speaks from a pedestal when he observes that "all this paraphernalia of pomp and pageantry costs a lot of money. But this is a minor issue. What really matters is the feudal culture of privilege it promotes, the damage it does to the growth of an egalitarian outlook, the noxious example that this level of extravagance and high living sets before the people..." This is odd, as the high priest of Indian broadcasting is hardly known for his humility or lightness of touch. For a person of many many summers who had to be accommodated in his latest position by relaxing the age limit, Gill comes out quite strongly as an angry man, whose heart is in the right place - as Andre Gunder Frank once said about his father, in the upper half and slightly to the left. Throughout the book, he pours venom and more on the corrupt of all hues even though most of it reads like the angry letters to the editor by citizens upset with the general degeneration of public life. Sample this: n "Our politicians profess to live for the people, and swear by them in every speech. But there is no other section of humanity which so flagrantly robs the people and works against their interests"; n "Except for Lutyens' Delhi, the rest of the city now presents a picture of total chaos. And the major credit for this situation goes to our politicians who have dedicated their lives to the service of the people"; n "Thousands of crores of public money has been stashed in secret foreign banks by corrupt politicians...Quite a few of these patriots take their vile secret to the grave when they happen to die suddenly...And these are the people whose statues are erected for public veneration". There is little of the experienced bureaucrat in the book, less of a person who claims in the preface of having `abiding academic interests'. For most part, Gill has merely summed up what is already known about the known cases of corruption in high places since the time of Jawaharlal Nehru. The rogues' gallery evokes little interest, while there are no new insights into the mega corruption cases like Bofors, HDW, Satish Sharma's predilections or the Karsan deal. One may perhaps argue that the subject and the times themselves are mundane, and they turn tracts of the times into mere exercises in shorthand scholarship, `bonsai academics', as it were. But then, had it not been for the fact that Gill has been an `insider' in the system all these years, there would have been little reason to pick up the book. One looked forward to reading about the many ingenuous ways the system breeds corruption, with juicy little known examples, but was disappointed. In the event, the book falls between two stools, neither does it satisfy the academic nor the lay reader interested in knowing the `unofficial official' version of corruption. At the end of the exercise, the reader is left wondering how the book can ever be described as `an incisive no holds barred account of corruption in India', as the jacket claims. (c)1998 Business Standard Ltd. Quellen:BUSINESS STANDARD 25/05/98 P11 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>> 23Okt1997 PHILIPPINES: The View from Taft Reaching out. By Dante Sy. The dependency theory - espoused by Celso Furtado, a Brazilian economist and contributor to the Spanish and Portuguese literature on dependency theory, and Andre Gunder Frank, a major dependency theorist from the USA - which is used in economic development analysis, suggests that the poverty or misery of third world countries (less developed countries) is generally the result of their dependence on first world countries (developed countries). Obviously, the premise of the theory is that transactions entered into by third world countries (whether of the trade, loan, grant or assistance type) with first world countries do not always result in their favor. This is so as first world countries are positioned as to be able to sway or dictate the terms of trade, loan, grant or assistance transactions in their favor. The theory also implies that some first world countries, in their desire to promote their own economic interests, may go to the extent of exploiting the resources or facilities of third world countries more for the former's benefit and less for the latter's. What is true of countries may also be true of people. It is not always absolute that people are poor because they opt to be so. Sometimes, there is poverty or misery because there are some members of society who take advantage of the poor or make use of their resources or facilities only for their own good. For instance, certain farm tenancy, household help or factory employment contracts are so structured as to practically condemn the poor farmer, domestic help or sweatshop hand to a life of penury. The creation of the Educational Research and Development Assistance (ERDA) Foundation, Inc. on September 19, 1974 is, therefore, a milestone, particularly as its efforts and initiatives are designed to provide self-help opportunities, specifically through the intervention of education for the poor to improve on their economic status. But more than providing these self-help opportunities, the ERDA is also a medium through which well-meaning individuals and institutions are able to make use of their resources and facilities no longer for their own good but for the good of others. That moneyed individuals and institutions can do so was underscored by the testimonials of Alvin Tejada and Rowena Picardal, both scholars of ERDA who were able to finish their architecture and political science courses through the financial assistance of their benefactors. As Alvin and Rowena put it on the occasion of the blessing and inauguration of the ERDA Development Center on Sept. 19, 1997 which coincided with ERDA's 23rd foundation anniversary, they would not be what they are today were it not for the scholarship program of the ERDA and the funding support extended to said program by the many individuals and institutions who see in their plentitude the need to reach out to the poor. More than Alvin and Rowena and the other beneficiaries of ERDA's self-help program, there are still many others who are just waiting for some magnanimous individuals or institutions to reach out to them through ERDA so that they may also overcome their financial hurdles and enhance their economic status. Would that we could all reach out to those in need? (C) Business World Publishing Corporation 1997. Quellen:BUSINESS WORLD (PHILIPPINES) 23/10/97 P4 <<...>> <<...>> <<...>>
< < <
Date Index > > > |
World Systems Network List Archives at CSF | Subscribe to World Systems Network |
< < <
Thread Index > > > |