< < <
Date Index
> > >
Re: Current position in the K-wave (corrected)
by Mike Alexander
06 September 2001 23:03 UTC
< < <
Thread Index
> > >
I haven't read Arrighi as of yet, but I can address the 1945-70 dating.  In his Long-wave rhythms in economic development and political behavior, Brian Berry develops the idea that there are two boom/bust cycles per K-cycle, not one.  The stock market analyst P.Q. Wall has given seasonal names to these periods: the A phase boom is Spring, the A phase bust is Summer, the B phase boom is Fall and the B phase bust is Winter.  My view is we are transitioning from Fall to Winter now.  The 1945-70 period corresponds to a Spring period. 
 
Seasons can be visualized in GDP by dividing the GDP by its long term trend value.  I obtain this trend by doing a running regression of ln(GDP) versus year over a 100 year period, centered on the year of interest.  Thus, the trend GDP for 1850 is obtained from the regression equation for the period 1800-1900.  After 1950 a fixed regression equation obtained from the 1900-2000 data is used, and before 1839 a fixed regression equation obtained from the 1789-1889 data is used.  Here is what a plot of GDP/GDP trend looks like:
 
http://csf.colorado.edu/authors/Alexander.Mike/Image138.gif
 
The fine line is the raw ratio, the heavy line is a running centered nine-year moving average.  The K-peaks and K-troughs show up as troughs on this plot and are labeled in bold.  Technically the K-peak is actually the Schumpeterian primary recession that comes immediately after the "true" K-peak in monetary terms.  Hence we have K-peaks in monetary variables in 1814, 1861/4, 1918/20 and 1981, and primary recession troughs in GDP immediately following in 1816, 1865, 1922 and 1983.  We have GDP troughs in 1789, 1843 and 1896 closely associated with monetary troughs in 1787/9, 1843, and 1897.  The GDP peaks at the transition from boom to bust in the middle of the upwave (A phase) and the downwave (B phase).  These peaks define the spring/summer and fall/winter transitions.  Hence we see spring peaks in 1803, 1853, and 1909 that correspond to Arrighi's 1970 growth peak.  Notice that each of these peaks occurs about 11 years before the following K-peak in 1814, 1864, 1920 and 1981.  The eleven year period from the GDP peak to the K-peak, plus the primary recession is the Summer period.  US stocks show a cycle analogous to that of GDP, which is the topic of my first book (see my sig file).  The GDP figure appears in that book as does the concept of seasons.  One can also find "seasons" in GDP in British and French GDP as shown in the Table below.  They also show up in 18th century British industrial production.

Table 4.1. Kondratiev seasonal cycles in British, French & U.S. GDP, and U.S. Stocks

K-season

U.K. / U. S. Prices1

U. S. GDP2

U. S. Stocks2

British GDP/ Indust Prod2,3

French GDP2

Fall

1711 (P)

--

--

1711-1721

--

Winter

--

--

--

1721-1742

--

Spring

1736 (T)

--

--

1742-1751

--

Summer

--

--

--

1751-1761

--

Fall

1774 (P)

--

--

1761-1768

--

Winter

--

--

--

1768-1781

--

Spring

1789 (T)

1789-1803

--

1781-1801

--

Summer

--

1803-1816

1802-1815 (bear)

1801-1820

--

Fall

1814 (P)

1816-1836

1815-1835 (bull)

1820-1839

--

Winter

--

1836-1844

1835-1843 (bear)

1839-1843

--

Spring

1843 (T)

1844-1853

1843-1853 (bull)

1843-1862

--

Summer

--

1853-1865

1853-1861 (bear)

1862-1868

--

Fall

1864 (P)

1865-1883

1861-1881 (bull)

1868-1874

--

Winter

--

1883-1896

1888-1896 (bear)

1874-1893

--

Spring

1896 (T)

1896-1909

1896-1906 (bull)

1893-1915

1889-1913

Summer

--

1909-1922

1906-1921 (bear)

1915-1921

1913-1919

Fall

1920 (P)

1922-1926

1921-1929 (bull)

1921-1929

1919-1929

Winter

--

1926-1949

1929-1949 (bear)

1929-1947

1929-1944

Spring

1946 (T)

1949-1970

1949-1966 (bull)

1947-1977

1944-19754

Summer

--

1970-1983?

1966-1982 (bear)

--

--

Fall

1981 (P)

1983-2001?

1982-2000 (bull)

--

--

1British price data in italics, U.S. price data in normal typeface (P indicates K-peak and R a trough).
2
Dates in bold mark Kondratiev peaks and troughs
3
Industrial Production-based values in italics
4
The data ends in 1975, at which point the trend was still up
 
The Depression and World War II really threw a wrench into the cycles.  Government economic management that was introduced in response to these events has produced  the twentieth century price revolution and practically eliminated the cycle in GDP.  The cycle in stocks is stronger than ever though.  GDP is pretty useless for detecting the cycle today. 
 
This seasonal structure to the production-defined K-cycle is a new thing that came with industrialization.  This structure can be related to Schumpeterian-type models for economic growth.  Before industrialization, production/trade cycles or what I call real cycles (as opposed to monetary cycles) tended to approximately align with the monetary cycles.  I characterize pre-industrial real cycles using the leading sector method as previously described.  Leading sectors also can be related to Schumpeterian models.  Post-industrial leading sector clusters or "new economies" necessarily peak before the monetary K-peak.  For the pre-industrial world, clusters of leading sectors may peak before or after the K-peak.
 
I obtained a set of monetary-based Kondratiev turning points and a set of real-based turning points.  The two are aligned in a statistically significant fashion.  The two can then be combined to form a composite cycle that compares well with Goldstein's scheme.

Table 4.4. The K-cycle turning points

My Work

Goldstein's Base Dating Scheme

Trough

Peak

Trough

Peak

1191

1224

--

--

1244

1272

--

--

1291

1316

1286

1316

1342

1370

1338

1370

--

--

1383

1392

1397

14421

1411

1439

14631

14892

1460

1483

--

--

1509

1529

1509

1557

1539

1559

1583

1597

1575

1595

1621

1650

1621

1650

1688

1718

1689

1720

1739

1769

1747

1762

1787

1813

1790

1814

1843

1864

1848

1872

1896

1920

1893

1917

1948

1981

1940

1980

1Obtained from leading sector data only because they were not clearly shown by prices.
2
The 1483 price peak was not well-characterized and so was averaged with the 1494 real peak to give 1489.
 
Goldstein has an extra cycle in the late 14th century and early 16th century.  The first doesn't show up in British prices (although it may in French prices, which is what Imbert used, from whom this cycle was obtained by Goldstein).  The second shows up clearly in monetary data, but was not confirmed by leading sectors.  It also does not show up in the social cycles.  
 
Mike Alexander,  author of
Stock Cycles: Why stocks won't beat money markets over the next 20 years.
http://www.net-link.net/~malexan/STOCK_CYCLES.htm
 
I'd much like to hear your detailed reactions to Arrighi's work, in particular, the Long 20th Century.  He and Wallerstein argue for a 1945-70 A phase by measurement of material production growth, followed by a period relative decline in growth rates.  However, Arrighi embeds these cycles within hegemonic cycles.  The end of a B phase is the start of a financial rebirth in which capital puts relatively more money into speculation than production.  Hence the stagflation of the '70s and the financial boom since (until now).  In other words, prices alone might be misleading.  Arrighi thus suggests that we distinguish the production and financial cycles from each other, and relate them to the rise and demise of hegemonies, the accompanying global governance structures of capitalism, and to structural changes such as core deindustrialization, semi-p industrialization (and attending changes in anti-systemic movements).
 
Elson Boles, Ph.D.
Dept. of Sociology
Saginaw Valley State University
 
< < <
Date Index
> > >
World Systems Network List Archives
at CSF
Subscribe to World Systems Network < < <
Thread Index
> > >