A  SIMULATION  OF  GLOBAL  EXPLOITATION
 
 

Gernot  Köhler

School of Computing and Information Management
Sheridan College
Oakville, Ontario, Canada L6H 2L1
e-mail:  gernot.kohler@sheridanc.on.ca

September 1999
 

1. ABSTRACT

Global income polarization ("the widening global gap") has been explained in various ways. My simulation assumes that some portion of global income polarization is due to global center-periphery exploitation. The simulation shows that even a small rate of global center-periphery exploitation can lead to significant global income polarization in the longer run. The abolition of this kind of center-periphery exploitation would lead to a closing of the global income gap.
 

2. GLOBAL EXPLOITATION

The term "global exploitation" is not well-defined in the literature. Several broad meanings of "global exploitation" are thinkable -- namely, (a) children's rights activists may think of the exploitation of children around the world; (b) feminists may think of "worldwide exploitation of women by men"; (c) others may think of "worldwide exploitation of workers by employers"; (d) yet others may think of "exploitation of poor countries by rich countries" or of "exploitation of the global periphery by the global center"; (e) yet others may think of "worldwide exploitation of non-whites by the white man" (or of ethnic groups X by ethnic group Y); and other notions. In the different meanings of the term, the two sides of the exploitative relationship are identified as different agents -- namely, children/adults, women/men; workers/employers; countries; ethno-cultural groups. My simulation uses the fourth meaning, namely, global center-periphery exploitation. This is close to, but not necessarily identical with, the term "unequal exchange", as used in the literature. Various mechanisms have been identified in the literature which can be considered as facets of "global exploitation", in the sense of center-periphery exploitation. These include: (1) the fact that the rules of the world economy are made by the center countries; (2) the fact that the transnational organizations regulating certain aspects of the world economy are dominated by the center countries; (3) the fact that the most powerful global corporations are corporations of the center countries; (4) unfair trade between center and periphery; (5) biased exchange rates between center and periphery; and other. Without going into the details of the discussions surrounding these issues, my simulation makes the assumption that the center countries (OECD countries) do exploit the rest of the world (non-OECD countries) through mechanisms of the mentioned kind. As a result center countries extract a certain amount of economic value, which I call "transfer value" (T), from the rest of the world which is due to the exploitative mechanisms rather than due to the center countries' own hard work and technological brilliance. In some historical empires this transfer value (T) was more explicit and was called "tribute" or "slave labour" and was extracted from the subdued peoples by the imperial country (e.g., in the Hapsburg or Ottoman or Chinese empires).
 

3. SIMULATION LOGIC

Simulation is a calculation exercise which can be used for constructing alternative "scenarios" (e.g., alternative ways of declaring taxes); for projecting "alternative futures" (e.g., alternative ecological developments); or for constructing "alternative histories". Simulations have also been called "What-If?-analysis". My simulation constructs an "alternative history" and pursues the question: What would have happened to the world income distribution between 1961 and 1989, if there had been less global exploitation?

The logic underlying this simulation can be explained with an example. Imagine two brothers (or sisters) -- LITTLE BROTHER and BIG BROTHER. Each brother has 100 dollars to invest. Both brothers invest their money in the same bank in two separate bank accounts. The bank gives, say, 2% interest per year. At the end of year 1, each brother will have $102; at the end of year 2, $104; and so on. The relation between the two accounts will remain 1 : 1 at the end of every year since the accounts accumulate in exactly the same manner and independently from each other. There is no income polarization.

Now introduce exploitation. Let us assume that BIG BROTHER is a bully and forces LITTLE BROTHER to hand over one half of the interest he earns every year. As a result, the situation at the end of year 1 is: BIG BROTHER has $103 [ = 102 + 1 (exploitation)] and LITTLE BROTHER has $101 [ = 102 - 1 (exploitation)]. The situation at the end of year 2 will be: BIG BROTHER has $106 [ = 103 + 2 (interest) + 1 (exploitation)] and LITTLE BROTHER has $102 [ = 101 + 2 (interest) - 1 (exploitation)]. At the end of year 3, BIG BROTHER will have $109 [ = 106 + 2 (interest) + 1 (exploitation)] and LITTLE BROTHER  will have $103 [ = 102 + 2 (interest) - 1 (exploitation)]. The relation between the two accounts at the end of year 3 is 109 : 103. In other words, income polarization is underway.

Next, apply this at the world level, with LITTLE BROTHER = periphery and BIG BROTHER = center, and assume that the center is the exploitative bully. Note that the historical data we have about GDP growth rates are "after-exploitation" -- namely, they include the effect of exploitation. Thus, the observed growth rate of OECD countries include gains from global exploitation; and the observed growth rates of non-OECD countries include losses from global exploitation. (The situation is similar to the difference between "gross income" and "net income" or "before tax income" and "after tax income".) Thus, if the center shows a historical growth rate of, say, 3% per annum and the exploitation rate was 1%, then we may claim that the center's historical growth rate of 3% was composed of 2% self-generated growth ("before-exploitation growth") plus 1% exploitation [3 = 2 + 1]. Similarly, if the periphery shows an historical growth rate of, say, 3% per annum and the exploitation rate was 1%, then we may claim that the periphery's historical growth rate of 3% was composed of 4% self-generated growth ("before-exploitation growth") minus 1% exploitation [3 = 4 -1]. The simulation thus operates with the two concepts of "before-exploitation growth rate" and "after-exploitation growth rate".

The simulation exercise proceeds in five broad steps -- namely,
(1) collect historical data
(2) make an assumption about the transfer value (T). Here I am assuming that the T value was 1.5% of the GDP of the OECD countries in every year (exploitation rate = 1.5%). Feel free to make other assumptions (it's a simulation!). The T value is the amount of gain (loss) due to global center-periphery exploitation. As empirical-historical support for a 1.5% rate, see Amin (1976: 144) and Köhler (1998: Table 2), who found a rate of "unequal exchange" for the years 1965 (1966) amounting to 1.5%  of the GDP of the industrialized countries (OECD, center).
(3) calculate alternative growth rates for center (OECD) and periphery (non-OECD) by removing the influence of exploitation (i.e., subtract the T value from OECD GDP and add the T value to non-OECD GDP). For the center, the resulting "before-exploitation growth rates" will be smaller than the historically observed (after-exploitation) growth rates; for the periphery the resulting "before exploitation growth rates" will be greater than the historically observed (after-exploitation) growth rates.
(4) recalculate the growth trajectories for 1961 - 1989 for center (OECD) and periphery (non-OECD), using the postulated "before-exploitation growth rates"
(5) display the results in graphical form

For further details of the calculations, see the Appendix, Table 6.
The calculations were done with a computer "spreadsheet" software.
 

4. SIMULATION RESULTS

The results of the simulation are summarized in four diagrams -- namely:
Figure 1 shows actual polarization of per capita incomes, 1961 - 1989 (historical data);
Figure 2 shows simulated per capita incomes, 1961 - 1989 (assuming and removing a global exploitation rate of 1.5% per annum);
Figure 3 shows the actual development of GDPs (aggregate incomes), 1961 - 1989 (historical data);
Figure 4 shows the simulated development of GDPs (aggregate incomes), 1961 -1989 (assuming and removing a global exploitation rate of 1.5% per annum).
 

Figure 1 shows the actual polarization of world income which took place betwen 1961 and 1989. The values are expressed in constant "international prices" (PPP dollars, 1985=100). The data source is Penn World Table (1999). The exact values for this and the other diagrams can be found in the Appendix, Tables 1 - 6.
 
 
 Figure 2 shows simulation results. After 1971-73 OECD income stays on a plateau around 8000 PPP dollars per capita. Non-OECD income increases to about 4000 PPP dollars per capita by 1989. The world income gap is closing.
 
Figure 3 shows the historical development of GDPs which took place between 1961 and 1989. Throughout the period, the combined GDP of non-OECD (with about 80% of world population) stays below the combined GDP of OECD (with about 20% of world population).
 
 
Figure 4 shows simulation results. Starting around 1972-73 the combined GDP of non-OECD moves ahead of the combined GDP of OECD.
 

5. DISCUSSION

The results of the simulation are somewhat of a surprise to myself. I had been studying "unequal exchange" along Emmanuel's and Amin's lines. My own estimates of unequal exchange between periphery and center of the world showed the same result as Amin's -- namely, 1.5% of center GDP for 1966 (Amin 1976: 144; Köhler 1998). This gave me the idea of simulating the development of world income distribution by making the assumption that "unequal exchange" had not taken place. In other words: What would have happened, if there had been no global exploitation (unequal exchange)? I was expecting some consequences in the direction of the simulation results, but not as strong an impact as the simulation shows. The simulation thus poses two challenges -- (1) methodological; (2) substantive. I leave the methodological challenge to others who may want to develop their own simulations of global exploitation, using different definitions, assumptions, values and algorithms.

On the praxeological side, the simulation sends a hopeful message, namely:  If political activists and/or socially responsible elites can raise enough consciousness and organize enough political pressure, so as  to reduce global exploitation by 1.5% per annum, the global income gap will begin to close within a number of years (far less than eternity!) -- by virtue of the logic of compounding, as the simulation shows.

On the analytic-theoretical side, the simulation raises various difficult questions which I cannot answer right now. Question 1: Is it plausible to think that, as the simulation shows, OECD per capita income would have stayed at a plateau after 1971-73? The implication of this is that all per capita income growth of the OECD countries after 1971-73 was due to global exploitation. If that was so, then some more research and theory would be nice to have in order support such a view. Question 2: Can the fact that the simulation shows some special role for the years 1971-73 be used as an indictment of global neoliberalism which abolished the preceding Keynesian-influenced international economic regime around that time (USA going off the gold standard, dismantling of the preceding Bretton-Woods system, deregulation of the old system, enforcement of neoliberal regulations, IMF "Structural Adjustment Policies", and other)? Question 3: What would the First World do without global exploitation? Are all the people who see a  technological superiority of the West wrong? Question 4: Is there truly such a thing as global exploitation (or, if you don't like this term, is there a transfer value (T))? "I don't know" is my answer to most these questions, except the last one -- I do believe that there is a transfer value T of some kind. It is the essence of a simulation to show something that is not real in an empirical sense. Potentialities are important for the understanding and evaluation of historical developments. If the Spanish Armada had not been destroyed in 1588, we might all be speaking Spanish today.
 

6. REFERENCES

Amin, S. (1976) Unequal Development. New York, USA: Monthly Review Press [translated from the 1973 French original]

Emmanuel, A. (1972) Unequal Exchange: A Study of the Imperialism of Trade. New York, USA: Monthly Review Press [translated from the 1969 French original]

Köhler, G. (1998), "Unequal Exchange 1965 - 1995: World Trend and World Tables", World-Systems Archive, Working Papers, /archive/papers/kohlertoc.htm

Penn World Table (Mark 5.6a) (1999) available online at: http://datacentre.chass.utoronto.ca:5680/pwt
 

7. APPENDIX -- TABLES

The simulation was done in a single computer spreadsheet with columns A - AC. The original spreadsheet is here broken up into 5 tables. The columns are numbered as in the original spreadsheet. Thus, you may load the material into your own spreadsheet and simulate something else. Notes to Tables 1-5 are given in Table 6, including method of calculation. Tables 1-3 (columns A - S) refer to the actual, historical situation, as captured in the statistical data available in the Penn World Table. Tables 4-5 (columns T - AC) contain the simulation exercise. The T value, which is central in this simulation, is in column (T). Abbreviations are explained in Table 6.

TABLE 1--HISTORICAL
TABLE 1 Cols. A - G 
       
 
hist
hist
hist
hist
hist
hist
 
N=121
N=24
N=24
N=97
N=97
N=97
 
World
OECD
OECD
non-OECD
non-OECD
non-OECD
YEAR
GDP
GDP 
GDP growth
GDP 
GDP growth
GDP as % of
     
rate
 
rate
World GDP
         
 
intlPr85
intlPr85
%pa
intlPr85
%pa
%
 
thousands
thousands
 
thousands
   
(A)
(B)
(C)
(D)
(E)
(F)
(G)
1961
6,644,104,915
4,197,078,117
 
2,447,026,798
 
37
1962
6,958,334,783
4,425,741,925
5.4
2,532,592,858
3.5
36
1963
7,318,210,382
4,647,760,802
5.0
2,670,449,580
5.4
36
1964
7,821,126,619
4,945,690,202
6.4
2,875,436,417
7.7
37
1965
8,232,636,791
5,209,411,377
5.3
3,023,225,414
5.1
37
1966
8,658,136,099
5,488,116,456
5.4
3,170,019,643
4.9
37
1967
9,002,641,628
5,688,121,612
3.6
3,314,520,016
4.6
37
1968
9,510,313,561
6,008,199,875
5.6
3,502,113,686
5.7
37
1969
10,089,946,152
6,332,236,056
5.4
3,757,710,096
7.3
37
1970
10,704,718,432
6,596,442,496
4.2
4,108,275,936
9.3
38
1971
11,142,091,771
6,825,657,455
3.5
4,316,434,316
5.1
39
1972
11,676,755,998
7,171,841,543
5.1
4,504,914,455
4.4
39
1973
12,437,495,139
7,614,357,468
6.2
4,823,137,671
7.1
39
1974
12,758,961,281
7,648,802,862
0.5
5,110,158,419
6.0
40
1975
12,928,493,353
7,582,721,503
-0.9
5,345,771,850
4.6
41
1976
13,539,756,819
7,954,236,256
4.9
5,585,520,563
4.5
41
1977
14,146,256,616
8,255,775,960
3.8
5,890,480,656
5.5
42
1978
14,795,395,856
8,604,173,926
4.2
6,191,221,930
5.1
42
1979
15,357,073,622
8,903,480,174
3.5
6,453,593,448
4.2
42
1980
15,775,665,903
8,970,184,755
0.7
6,805,481,148
5.5
43
1981
16,138,431,535
9,109,550,613
1.6
7,028,880,922
3.3
44
1982
16,244,188,844
9,060,345,894
-0.5
7,183,842,950
2.2
44
1983
16,709,104,924
9,318,985,537
2.9
7,390,119,387
2.9
44
1984
17,499,126,460
9,771,434,305
4.9
7,727,692,155
4.6
44
1985
18,172,039,417
10,087,409,006
3.2
8,084,630,411
4.6
44
1986
18,694,145,877
10,387,726,851
3.0
8,306,419,026
2.7
44
1987
19,315,927,688
10,743,245,634
3.4
8,572,682,054
3.2
44
1988
20,234,661,996
11,249,847,382
4.7
8,984,814,614
4.8
44
1989
20,941,943,905
11,650,765,699
3.6
9,291,178,206
3.4
44
             
     
avg=
 
avg=
 
     
3.7
 
4.9
 
     
std=
 
std=
 
     
1.9
 
1.6
 
 

TABLE 2--HISTORICAL
TABLE 2 Cols. H - P
                 
 
hist
hist
hist
hist
hist
hist
hist
hist
hist
 
N=121
N=24 
N=97
proportion
N=121
N=24
N=97
ratio
difference
 
World 
OECD
non-OECD
OECD 
World
OECD
non-OECD
OECD 
OECD
YEAR
POP
POP
POP
POP as %
GDP/cap
GDP/cap
GDP/cap
GDP/cap
GDP/cap
       
of World
     
to
less
     
POP 
non-OECD
non-OECD
 
GDP/cap
GDP/cap
 
 
persons
persons
persons
%
intlPr85
intlPr85
intlPr85
ratio
intlPr85
 
thousands
thousands
thousands
           
(A)
(H)
(I)
(J)
(K)
(L)
(M)
(N)
(O)
(P)
1961
2,858,189
645,972
2,212,217
23
2325
6497
1106
5.9
5391
1962
2,909,787
654,346
2,255,441
22
2391
6764
1123
6.0
5641
1963
2,972,467
662,313
2,310,154
22
2462
7017
1156
6.1
5862
1964
3,033,118
670,095
2,363,023
22
2579
7381
1217
6.1
6164
1965
3,095,949
677,836
2,418,113
22
2659
7685
1250
6.1
6435
1966
3,161,770
684,839
2,476,931
22
2738
8014
1280
6.3
6734
1967
3,226,711
691,232
2,535,479
21
2790
8229
1307
6.3
6922
1968
3,292,485
696,730
2,595,755
21
2888
8623
1349
6.4
7274
1969
3,363,212
704,386
2,658,826
21
3000
8990
1413
6.4
7576
1970
3,434,699
711,783
2,722,916
21
3117
9267
1509
6.1
7759
1971
3,492,117
719,319
2,772,798
21
3191
9489
1557
6.1
7932
1972
3,563,935
726,274
2,837,661
20
3276
9875
1588
6.2
8287
1973
3,634,780
732,356
2,902,424
20
3422
10397
1662
6.3
8735
1974
3,705,986
739,360
2,966,626
20
3443
10345
1723
6.0
8623
1975
3,775,319
745,870
3,029,449
20
3424
10166
1765
5.8
8402
1976
3,842,584
750,961
3,091,623
20
3524
10592
1807
5.9
8785
1977
3,909,379
756,458
3,152,921
19
3619
10914
1868
5.8
9045
1978
3,977,004
762,000
3,215,004
19
3720
11292
1926
5.9
9366
1979
4,046,192
767,659
3,278,533
19
3795
11598
1968
5.9
9630
1980
4,115,802
773,680
3,342,122
19
3833
11594
2036
5.7
9558
1981
4,186,282
779,383
3,406,899
19
3855
11688
2063
5.7
9625
1982
4,259,580
784,597
3,474,983
18
3814
11548
2067
5.6
9480
1983
4,333,177
789,442
3,543,735
18
3856
11805
2085
5.7
9719
1984
4,405,899
793,991
3,611,908
18
3972
12307
2140
5.8
10167
1985
4,480,046
798,728
3,681,318
18
4056
12629
2196
5.8
10433
1986
4,557,700
803,472
3,754,228
18
4102
12929
2213
5.8
10716
1987
4,637,452
808,305
3,829,147
17
4165
13291
2239
5.9
11052
1988
4,718,125
813,368
3,904,757
17
4289
13831
2301
6.0
11530
1989
4,797,981
817,538
3,980,443
17
4365
14251
2334
6.1
11917
 

TABLE 3 -- HISTORICAL
TABLE 3 Cols. Q - S
     
 
hist
hist
hist
 
N=121
N=24
N=97
 
World
OECD
non-OECD
YEAR
GDP/cap
GDP/cap
GDP/cap
 
growth rate 
growth rate
growth rate
based on
based on
based on
intlPr85
intlPr85
intlPr85
     
 
%pa
%pa
%pa
       
(A)
(Q)
(R)
(S)
1961
     
1962
2.9
4.1
1.5
1963
3.0
3.8
2.9
1964
4.7
5.2
5.3
1965
3.1
4.1
2.7
1966
3.0
4.3
2.4
1967
1.9
2.7
2.1
1968
3.5
4.8
3.2
1969
3.9
4.2
4.8
1970
3.9
3.1
6.8
1971
2.4
2.4
3.2
1972
2.7
4.1
2.0
1973
4.4
5.3
4.7
1974
0.6
-0.5
3.7
1975
-0.5
-1.7
2.4
1976
2.9
4.2
2.4
1977
2.7
3.0
3.4
1978
2.8
3.5
3.1
1979
2.0
2.7
2.2
1980
1.0
-0.0
3.4
1981
0.6
0.8
1.3
1982
-1.1
-1.2
0.2
1983
1.1
2.2
0.9
1984
3.0
4.3
2.6
1985
2.1
2.6
2.6
1986
1.1
2.4
0.7
1987
1.5
2.8
1.2
1988
3.0
4.1
2.8
1989
1.8
3.0
1.4
 

TABLE 4 -- SIMULATION
TABLE 4  Cols. T - X
     
sim
sim
sim
sim
sim
 
 
N=24
N=97
N=121
N=97
 
OECD
non-OECD
control:
non-OECD
 
T
hypoth. GDP
hypoth GDP
difference
hypoth GDP
YEAR
transfer value
using historical
using historical
hypGGDP/
as % of
 
= 1.5% of
GDP growth rate
GDP growth rate
histGGDP
hypoth GGDP
OECD GDP
less T value
plus T value
as % of
(1961 GDP=given)
(1961 GDP=given)
hist GGDP
intlPr85
intlPr85
intlPr85
%
%
 
thousands
thousands
thousands
     
(T)
(U)
(V)
(W)
(X)
(A)
 
4,197,078,117
2,447,026,798
 
 
1961
66,386,129
4,359,355,796
2,598,978,987
0.0
37
1962
69,716,412
4,508,327,978
2,810,165,720
-0.0
38
1963
74,185,353
4,723,134,143
3,100,062,684
-0.0
40
1964
78,141,171
4,896,846,694
3,337,537,983
-0.0
41
1965
82,321,747
5,076,507,722
3,581,915,563
-0.0
41
1966
85,321,824
5,176,190,667
3,830,513,390
-0.0
43
1967
90,122,998
5,377,338,888
4,137,434,012
-0.0
43
1968
94,983,541
5,572,367,729
4,534,381,845
-0.2
45
1969
98,946,637
5,705,922,759
5,056,351,904
-0.5
47
1970
102,384,862
5,801,808,837
5,414,932,318
-0.7
48
1971
107,577,623
5,988,487,688
5,758,956,767
-0.6
49
1972
114,215,362
6,243,773,124
6,279,979,797
-0.7
50
1973
114,732,043
6,157,286,304
6,768,428,002
-1.3
52
1974
113,740,823
5,990,349,987
7,194,239,883
-2.0
55
1975
119,313,544
6,164,533,098
7,636,202,765
-1.9
55
1976
123,836,639
6,274,389,730
8,176,963,321
-2.2
57
1977
129,062,609
6,410,109,575
8,723,504,657
-2.3
58
1978
133,552,203
6,499,540,527
9,226,741,420
-2.4
59
1979
134,552,771
6,413,682,100
9,864,390,155
-3.2
61
1980
136,643,259
6,376,685,429
10,324,846,306
-3.5
62
1981
135,905,188
6,206,336,937
10,688,377,932
-4.0
63
1982
139,784,783
6,243,720,310
11,135,068,160
-4.0
64
1983
146,571,515
6,400,289,470
11,790,277,707
-4.0
65
1984
151,311,135
6,455,941,764
12,486,175,903
-4.2
66
1985
155,815,903
6,492,329,282
12,984,529,624
-4.2
67
1986
161,148,685
6,553,379,837
13,561,898,603
-4.1
67
1987
168,747,711
6,693,659,192
14,382,635,966
-4.2
68
1988
174,761,485
6,757,444,105
15,047,815,585
-4.1
69
1989
           
 

TABLE 5--SIMULATION
TABLE 5 Cols. Y-AC        
sim
sim
sim
sim
sim
 
N=24
N=97
ratio
difference
N=121
 
OECD 
non-OECD
OECD GDP/cap
OECD GDP/cap
World 
 
GDP/cap
GDP/cap
to
less
GDP/cap
YEAR
   
non-OECD
non-OECD
   
GDP/cap
GDP/cap
 
   
intlPr85
intlPr85
ratio
intlPr85
intlPr85
 
           
(Y)
(Z)
(AA)
(AB)
(AC)
(A)
6497
1106
5.9
5391
2325
1961
6662
1152
5.8
5510
2391
1962
6807
1216
5.6
5591
2462
1963
7048
1312
5.4
5737
2579
1964
7224
1380
5.2
5844
2660
1965
7413
1446
5.1
5967
2738
1966
7488
1511
5.0
5978
2791
1967
7718
1594
4.8
6124
2890
1968
7911
1705
4.6
6206
3005
1969
8016
1857
4.3
6159
3133
1970
8066
1953
4.1
6113
3212
1971
8245
2029
4.1
6216
3296
1972
8526
2164
3.9
6362
3446
1973
8328
2282
3.7
6046
3488
1974
8031
2375
3.4
5657
3492
1975
8209
2470
3.3
5739
3592
1976
8294
2593
3.2
5701
3697
1977
8412
2713
3.1
5699
3805
1978
8467
2814
3.0
5652
3887
1979
8290
2952
2.8
5338
3955
1980
8182
3031
2.7
5151
3990
1981
7910
3076
2.6
4834
3966
1982
7909
3142
2.5
4767
4011
1983
8061
3264
2.5
4797
4129
1984
8083
3392
2.4
4691
4228
1985
8080
3459
2.3
4622
4273
1986
8108
3542
2.3
4566
4338
1987
8230
3683
2.2
4546
4467
1988
8266
3780
2.2
4485
4545
1989
           
 

TABLE 6 -- NOTES for TABLES 1 - 5



ABBREVIATIONS

%pa         percent per annum
avg         average
GDP         gross domestic product
GDP/cap     gross domestic product per capita
GGDP        global gross domestic product (world GDP)
hist        historical data, based on Penn World Tables (not simulated)
hypoth      hypothetical (=simulated)
intlPr85    international prices in constant 1985 values(i.e., purchasing power
            parity dollars,with US dollar 1985=100)
N           number of countries upon which the information is based
OECD        24 countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
non-OECD    97 countries which are not OECD, including China,India,Indonesia,USSR
POP         population
PWT         Penn World Table (data source)
sim         simulated values
std         standard deviation
T           transfer value (aggregate)
 

DATA SOURCE
Penn World Table (Mark 5.6a)
(Col. B,C,E: GDP from Penn World Table,using variable RGDPCH from source, multiplied by variable POP from source)(Col. H,I,J: variable POP in source).
 
CALCULATIONS
Column
A     none
B,C,E from source: using RGDPCH * POP from PWT
D     growth rate for col. C
F     growth rate for col. E
G     = (E/B)*100
H,I,J from source: using POP from PWT
K     =(I/H)*100
L     =B/H
M     =C/I
N     =E/J
O     =M/N
P     =M - N
Q     growth rate for col. L
R     growth rate for col. M
S     growth rate for col. N
T     =C * 0.015
U     U1961=given=C1961
      U1962=U1961*(1+(D1962/100)) - T1962
      and so on for the other years
V     V1961=given=E1961
      V1962=V1961*(1+(F1962/100)) + T1962
      and so on for the other years
W     =((B-U-V)/B)*100
X     =(V/(U+V))*100
Y     =U/I
Z     =V/J
AA    =Y/Z
AB    =Y - Z
AC    =(U+V)/H

INCLUSION/EXCLUSION OF COUNTRIES
The world has more than N=121 countries and more than N=97 non-OECD countries. I excluded countries on grounds of data availability. Only those countries are included which have complete data series for 1961-1989 in the source (Penn World Table). China,India, Indonesia and USSR are included. Some oil-producing countries and several countries of Eastern Europe are excluded, as are various other countries. The following countries are included in the study:
 
Ordered by continents as in Penn World Table:

Africa
America, North and Central
America, South
Asia, incl. "South-West Asia" = Arabian peninsula, incl. Israel and Syria
Europe, incl. USSR and Turkey
Oceania

N=121
ALGERIA
ANGOLA
BENIN
BOTSWANA
BURKINA FASO
BURUNDI
CAMEROON
CAPE VERDE IS.
CENTRAL AFR.R.
CHAD
COMOROS
CONGO
EGYPT
GABON
GAMBIA
GHANA
GUINEA
GUINEA-BISS
IVORY COAST
KENYA
LESOTHO
MADAGASCAR
MALAWI
MALI
MAURITANIA
MAURITIUS
MOROCCO
MOZAMBIQUE
NAMIBIA
NIGER
NIGERIA
REUNION
RWANDA
SENEGAL
SEYCHELLES
SIERRA LEONE
SOMALIA
SOUTH AFRICA
SWAZILAND
TOGO
TUNISIA
UGANDA
ZAIRE
ZAMBIA
ZIMBABWE
BARBADOS
CANADA
COSTA RICA
DOMINICAN REP.
EL SALVADOR
GUATEMALA
HAITI
HONDURAS
JAMAICA
MEXICO
NICARAGUA
PANAMA
PUERTO RICO
TRINIDAD&TOBAGO
U.S.A.
ARGENTINA
BOLIVIA
BRAZIL
CHILE
COLOMBIA
ECUADOR
GUYANA
PARAGUAY
PERU
SURINAME
URUGUAY
VENEZUELA
BANGLADESH
CHINA
HONG KONG
INDIA
INDONESIA
IRAN
ISRAEL
JAPAN
JORDAN
KOREA, REP.
MALAYSIA
MYANMAR
PAKISTAN
PHILIPPINES
SAUDI ARABIA
SINGAPORE
SRI LANKA
SYRIA
TAIWAN
THAILAND
AUSTRIA
BELGIUM
CYPRUS
CZECHOSLOVAKIA
DENMARK
FINLAND
FRANCE
GERMANY, WEST
GREECE
ICELAND
IRELAND
ITALY
LUXEMBOURG
MALTA
NETHERLANDS
NORWAY
PORTUGAL
ROMANIA
SPAIN
SWEDEN
SWITZERLAND
TURKEY
U.K.
U.S.S.R.
YUGOSLAVIA
AUSTRALIA
FIJI
NEW ZEALAND
PAPUA N.GUINEA



*end of table
*end of article